Networks as Public Infrastructure: Externalities, Efficiency, and Implementation

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12139
Published date01 April 2016
Date01 April 2016
AuthorHANS HALLER
NETWORKS AS PUBLIC INFRASTRUCTURE:EXTERNALITIES,
EFFICIENCY,AND IMPLEMENTATION
HANS HALLER
Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University
Abstract
First, a noncooperative model of network formation is investigated
where link formation is one-sided and information flow is two-way. For
that model, the relationship between different notions of efficient net-
works is studied: Pareto-optimal networks on the one hand and welfare-
maximizing networks on the other hand. Strategic network formation
is compared with funding schemes for public goods. Second, we ex-
tend the model and review earlier findings how a preexisting network
affects existence of Nash equilibria and efficiency of Nash equilibrium
outcomes of the strategic network formation game. It can foster or
prohibit existence of Nash equilibria. It can improve or worsen equi-
librium welfare. Finally, we treat the preexisting network as public in-
frastructure and design and analyze a subscription game for the public
provision of that infrastructure.
1. Introduction
The standard competitive equilibrium model—of pure exchange or with production—
assumes private goods without externalities. Allowing for externalities renders the anal-
ysis more cumbersome and, as a rule, affects the welfare conclusions. Introduction of
public goods leads to the Samuelsonian characterization of Pareto-optimal allocations
and implementation of the latter by means of mechanisms different from the standard
market mechanism, for instance by means of personalized or Lindahl prices. Both the
treatment of externalities and of public goods are considered special fields of microe-
conomic theory. In contrast, externalities are the essence of strategic game theory and
its applications, like those in industrial organization and other areas of economics. A
strategic game where none of the players is affected by the actions of others is justifiably
termed “inessential.”
Following the seminal contributions of Jackson and Wolinsky (1996) and Bala and
Goyal (2000) and the less well-known earlier example by Myerson (1991, p. 448), a
sizeable game-theoretic literature on network formation has emerged. The aim of the
current paper is to address several issues that arise when (a) a network is viewed as a
public infrastructure and (b) the network or part of it is the outcome of a game in
Hans Haller,Department of Economics, Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Blacksburg,
VA 24061 (haller@vt.edu). The comments of a referee and the suggestions of an associate editor are
appreciated.
Received August 22, 2014; Accepted September 21, 2014.
C2015 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 18 (2), 2016, pp. 193–211.
193
194 Journal of Public Economic Theory
strategic form. The main issues to be addressed or at least touched upon in a first pass
are network externalities (and public good features of networks), efficiency, and imple-
mentation; and those are obviously related.
In accordance with my prior work and for ease of exposition, I shall adhere to
the purely noncooperative approach of Bala and Goyal (2000) where addition and
deletion of links are unilateral decisions of the player from whom the respective links
originate.1More specifically, I shall focus on the so-called two-way flow connections
model `
alaGaleotti, Goyal, and Kamphorst (2006) both as a benchmark and an il-
lustrative prototype. That model incorporates cost and value heterogeneity. A player
receives valuable information from others not only through direct links, but also via
indirect links. The player incurs the cost of the direct links she initiates. Before contin-
uing the detailed description of the model, I make a digression on each of the three
themes, network externalities (and public good features of networks), efficiency, and
implementation.
1.1. Network Externalities
A strategic network formation game like any interesting strategic game inherently
involves externalities. So-called “network externalities” prove relevant for network
formation as well as network utilization, for both positive and normative analysis. A
classic and popular example for positive network externalities or “network effects” is
the telephone. Having a telephone is only of interest to the user if there is a significant
number of other users one can reach (and wants to reach) through the same network.
If additional users join the network, then they increase the value of the telephone to the
already existing users, even if that is not their intention. The two-way flow connections
model shares this property. If a player creates a direct link to another player, the
initiating player receives valuable information from the other player. In addition, the
first player receives valuable information from third players via indirect links and other
players receive valuable information from him through direct and indirect links. A
player can only benefit and never gets harmed when others create links.
The telephone also illustrates the possibility of negative network externalities or
“congestion effects.” If too many users attempt to make calls simultaneously, service
may be disrupted, delayed, or noisy. This was particularly the case before the digital age
because of overloaded lines and relays, but can still occur nowadays. Modifications of
the two-way flow connections model can accommodate negative network externalities.
I will briefly comment on such model variations in Section 7. However, the emphasis of
the paper is going to be on positive network externalities.
1.2. Local Public Good Aspects of Networks
If in the standard two-way flow connections model (without decay and with perfectly
reliable links), an isolated player forms a link to another player, then the first player gets
access to all the information available within the connected component of the second
player. He would receive the same information when establishing instead a link to
another player of that connected component. However, the costs of link formation may
be different. Investing in one of these links is like paying a fee to enter the particular
1In contrast, pairwise stability `
alaJackson and Wolinsky (2005) treats addition of a link in a network
as a bilateral decision by the two players involved, whereas severance of a link constitutes a unilateral
decision.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT