Network Formation under Multiple Sources of Externalities

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12177
AuthorSUMIT JOSHI,AHMED SABER MAHMUD
Date01 April 2016
Published date01 April 2016
NETWORK FORMATION UNDER MULTIPLE SOURCES
OF EXTERNALITIES
SUMIT JOSHI
George Washington University
AHMED SABER MAHMUD
Johns Hopkins University
Abstract
The architecture of social and economic networks is often explained in
terms of the externalities shaping the link-forming incentives of play-
ers. We make two contributions to this literature. First, we bring into
its ambit the linear-quadratic utility model. Since players’ utilities are
now a function of their network centralities, this permits endogenizing
their locational incentives in a network. Second, we show that the mode
of transmission of externalities can be crucial in dictating the topology
of equilibrium networks. We consider two alternative modes for chan-
neling externalities. Both have the same primary source (direct links)
but a different secondary source (global effects vs. indirect links). We
characterize equilibrium networks for different positive–negative com-
binations of primary–secondary externalities for both modes. We show
that the mode of transmission influences the equilibrium architecture
when externalities from the primary source are positive;whentheseex-
ternalities are negative, the equilibrium network is empty.
1. Introduction
The equilibrium configuration of interconnections among players that emerges en-
dogenously as players evaluate the benefits and costs of establishing bilateral links has
occupied an important strand in the network literature.1The existing literature has at-
tempted to explain the equilibrium network architecture in terms of the externalities that
1Please see Goyal (2007) and Jackson (2008) for a survey of this literature in the context of both
directed and undirected networks.
Sumit Joshi, Department of Economics, George Washington University 2125 G Street NW, Washing-
ton, DC 20052 (sumios@gwu.edu). Ahmed S. Mahmud, Applied Economics Program, Johns Hop-
kins University, Suite 104, 1717 Massachusetts Avenue NW, Washington DC 20036 (amahmud2@
jhu.edu).
We would like to thank participants at the Networks and Externalities conference (February 2013)
at Louisiana State University. Wewould also like to thank an associate editor and two referees for their
detailed comments and suggestions that have significantly improved the paper. Weremain responsible
for any errors.
Received April 30, 2013; Accepted June 5, 2015.
C2016 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 18 (2), 2016, pp. 148–167.
148
Multiple Sources of Externalities 149
bear upon players by virtue of their position in the network architecture. Our objective
in this paper is twofold. First, we bring into the ambit of the endogenous network forma-
tion literature the linear-quadratic specification of utility which now forms the bedrock
for many games on an exogenously fixed network.2Second, exploiting the tractability
offered by the linear-quadratic model, we demonstrate that the mode of transmission of ex-
ternalities is an equally important determinant in shaping the topology of equilibrium
networks. We now elaborate on each of these objectives.
The linear-quadratic specification of utility has an important feature that explains
its popularity for Nash games on a fixed network: the Nash action and reduced util-
ity of players is a function of their Katz–Bonacich centrality in a network.3In some
games (e.g., the oligopoly game of Example 1 in Section 3 below), Nash actions and
reduced utility are increasing in network centrality. In other games (e.g., provision of
public goods in Bramoull´
e, Kranton, and Amours 2014), higher Nash action levels are
no longer associated with the most central players; in fact players with greater centrality
can free ride on the actions of those less central (Ballester and Calv´
o-Armengol 2010,
example 11). These results lend special impetus toward endogenizing the network for-
mation process and systematically examining the motivation of players to assume, or not
assume, a central position in the network with an eye toward the subsequent game to
be played on the ensuing network. Accordingly, we posit a two-stage game where in the
first stage players form a network and in the second stage they engage in a Nash game
contingent on the network. Inducting backward from the Nash game in actions, players
weigh the benefits and costs of linking with each other. Our first objective is to charac-
terize the network architecture that ensues with particular emphasis on the centrality of
the locations occupied by players in the network.
Our second objective is to investigate within the context of the linear-quadratic util-
ity model two alternative modes of channeling externalities. Our main thesis is that the
mode of transmission of externalities can dictate the architecture of equilibrium net-
works. The two modes that we consider have a primary source and a secondary source
for transmitting externalities. We present examples to show that externalities from ei-
ther source can be positive or negative. We characterize the equilibrium networks for
different positive–negative combinations of primary–secondary externalities for both
modes. In the process, we demonstrate that the mode of transmission has definite im-
plications for the equilibrium network topology when externalities from the primary
source are positive. When these externalities are negative, the equilibrium architecture
is always empty and thus robust to the mode of transmission.
The first mechanism for transmitting externalities is based on Ballester , Calv´
o-
Armengol, and Zenou (2006). The primary source is local interaction (flow of exter-
nalities through direct links or neighbors within a network) while the secondary source
is global interaction (externalities transmitted without the aegis of the network). We
say that strategic local externalities exist and are negative (respectively, positive) when
an increase in the actions of neighbors in a network decreases (respectively, increases)
the utility of a player. Similarly, strategic global externalities are negative (respectively,
2This utility specification was introduced by Ballester, Calv´
o-Armengol, and Zenou (2006) and has
found numerous applications in the literature on games on networks. These include education (Calv´
o-
Armengol, Patacchini, amnd Zenou 2009), crime (Ballester, Calv´
o-Armengol, and Zenou 2010), con-
formity (Patacchini and Zenou 2012), and public goods provision (Bramoull´
eet al. 2014). Please see
Jackson and Zenou (2012) for a survey and Ballester and Calv´
o-Armengol (2010) for extensions.
3Please see Section 3 for the Katz–Bonacich measure, or Bonacich (1987) and Jackson (2008, section
2.2.4).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT