A multi‐country dynamic factor model with stochastic volatility for euro area business cycle analysis

AuthorFlorian Huber,Michael Pfarrhofer,Philipp Piribauer
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/for.2667
Received: 4 September 2019 Accepted: 12 January 2020
DOI: 10.1002/for.2667
RESEARCH ARTICLE
A multi-country dynamic factor model with stochastic
volatility for euro area business cycle analysis
Florian Huber1Michael Pfarrhofer1Philipp Piribauer2
1Salzburg Centre of European Union
Studies, University of Salzburg, Salzburg,
Austria
2Austrian Institute of Economic Research
(WIFO), Vienna, Austria
Correspondence
Florian Huber, Salzburg Centre of
European Union Studies, University of
Salzburg, Mönchsberg 2a, 5020 Salzburg,
Austria.
Email: florian.huber@sbg.ac.at
Funding information
Oesterreichische Nationalbank,
Grant/AwardNumber: 17382;
Austrian Science Fund (FWF),
Grant/AwardNumber: ZK 35
Abstract
This paper develops a dynamic factor model that uses euro area country-specific
information on output and inflation to estimate an area-wide measure of the
output gap. Our model assumes that output and inflation can be decomposed
into country-specific stochastic trends and a common cyclical component.
Comovement in the trends is introduced by imposing a factor structure on the
shocks to the latent states. We moreover introduce flexible stochastic volatil-
ity specifications to control for heteroscedasticity in the measurement errors
and innovations to the latent states. Carefully specified shrinkage priors allow
for pushing the model towards a homoscedastic specification, if supported
by the data. Our measure of the output gap closely tracks other commonly
adopted measures, with small differences in magnitudes and timing. To assess
whether the model-based output gap helps in forecasting inflation, we perform
an out-of-sample forecasting exercise. The findings indicate that our approach
yields superior inflation forecasts, both in terms of point and density predictions.
KEYWORDS
dynamic factor model, European business cycles, factor stochastic volatility, inflation forecasting
1INTRODUCTION
Effective policy making in central banks such as the Euro-
pean Central Bank (ECB) requires accurate measures of
latent quantities such as the output gap to forecast key
quantities of interest like inflation across euro area (EA)
member states. Since using aggregate EA data potentially
masks important country-specific dynamics, exploiting
country-level information could help in obtaining more
reliable estimates of the output gap that is consequently
used in Phillips curve-type models to forecast inflation.
In this paper, we exploit cross-sectional information
on output and inflation dynamics to construct a
multi-country model for the EA. The proposed framework
aims to combine the literature on output gap modeling
(see, among many others, Basistha & Nelson, 2007;
Kuttner, 1994; Orphanides & Van Norden, 2002; Planas
et al., 2008) that focuses on estimating the output gap based
on data for a single country/regional aggregate, the liter-
ature on dynamic factor models (Breitung & Eickmeier,
2015; Jarocinski & Lenza, 2018; Kim & Nelson, 1999; Kose
et al., 2003; Otrok & Whiteman, 1998), and the literature
on inflation forecasting (Stock & Watson, 1999, 2007).
Our model assumes that country-specific business cycles
are driven by a common latent factor, effectively exploit-
ing cross-sectional information in the data. Moreover, we
assume that output and inflation feature a nonstationary
country-specific component. To control for potential
comovement in these trend terms, we assume that the cor-
responding shocks to the states feature a factor structure.
The resulting factor model features stochastic volatility
(SV) in the spirit of Aguilar and West (2000) and thus pro-
vides a parsimonious way of controlling for heteroscedas-
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons AttributionLicense, which permits use, distribution and reproduction in any medium, providedthe
original work is properly cited.
© 2020 The Authors. Journal of Forecasting published by John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Journal of Forecasting. 2020;39:911–926. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/for 911
HUBER ET AL.
ticity. Since successful forecasting models typically allow
for SV (Clark, 2011; Clark & Ravazzolo, 2015; Huber,
2016; Huber & Feldkircher, 2019), we also allow for time
variation in the error variances across the remaining state
innovations and the measurement errors. One method-
ological key innovation is the introduction of global–local
shrinkage priors on the error variances of the state
equations describing the law of motion of the logarithmic
volatility components, effectively shrinking the system
towards a homoscedastic specification, if applicable.
This increased flexibility, however, is costly in terms
of additional parameters to estimate. We thus follow
the recent literature on state-space modeling (Belmonte
et al., 2014; Bitto & Frühwirth-Schnatter, 2019; Feldkircher
et al., 2017; Frühwirth-Schnatter & Wagner, 2010; Kastner
& Frühwirth-Schnatter, 2014) and exploit a noncentered
parametrization of the model (see Frühwirth-Schnatter
& Wagner, 2010) to test whether SV is supported by the
data. The noncentered parametrization allows treating the
square root of the process innovationvariances as standard
regression coefficients, implying that conventional shrink-
age priors can be used. Here we follow Griffin and Brown
(2010) and use a variant of the Normal-Gamma (NG)
shrinkage prior that introduces a global shrinkage compo-
nent that applies to all process variances simultaneously,
forcing them towards zero.Local shrinkage parameters are
then used to drag sufficient posterior mass away fromzero
even in the presence of strong global shrinkage, allowing
for nonzero process variances if required.
When applied to data for 10 EA countries over the time
period from 1997:Q1 to 2018:Q4, we find that our out-
put gap measure closely tracks other measures reported in
previous studies (Jarocinski & Lenza, 2018; Planas et al.,
2008) as well as gaps obtained by utilizing standard tools
commonly used in policy institutions. We moreover per-
form historical decompositions to gauge the importance
of area-wide as opposed to country-specific shocks for
describing inflation movements. These measures reveal
that inflation is strongly driven by common business cycle
dynamics, underlining the importance of controlling for a
common business cycle. Wethen turn to assessing whether
there exists a Phillips curve across EA countries by sim-
ulating a negative one standard deviation business cycle
shock. This exercise points towards a robust relationship
between the common gap component and inflation, with
magnitudes differing across countries.
The main part of the empirical application applies our
modeling approach to forecast inflation, paying particular
attention to whether the inclusion of a common output
gap improves predictive capabilities. Since inflation across
countries is driven by a term measuring trend inflation and
the output gap, our framework can be interpretedas a New
Keynesian Phillips curve, akin to Stella and Stock (2013).
Compared to a set of simpler alternatives that range from
univariate benchmark models to models that use alterna-
tive ways to calculate the output gap, the proposed model
yields more precise point and density forecasts for infla-
tion.
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows.
Section 2 describes the econometric framework. After
providing an overview of the model, we discuss the
Bayesian prior choice and briefly summarize the main
steps involved in estimating the model. Section 3 presents
the empirical application, starting with a summary of the
data set, and inspects various key features of our model.
The section moreover studies the dynamic impact of busi-
ness cycle shocks to the country-specific output and infla-
tion series. In a forecasting exercise, Section 4 compares
the out-of-sample predictive performance of our model
with other specifications. The final section summarizes
and concludes the paper.
2ECONOMETRIC FRAMEWORK
2.1 A dynamic factor model for the EA
In this section we describe the framework to estimate the
EA output gap using disaggregate country-level informa-
tion. Let it and it denote output and inflation for country
i=1,,Nin period t=1,,T, respectively. For
notational simplicity, we define k∈{, }.
Country-specific output and inflation are driven by
unobserved common nonstationary trend components
kit that aim to capture low-frequency movements,
while a common cyclical component gttracks mid- to
high-frequency fluctuations in inflation and output. These
unobserved (latent) quantities are related to the observed
quantities through a set of measurement equations:
it =it +igt+it,(1)
it =it +igt+it,(2)
kit (0,ehkit).(3)
These equations imply that the trend components can
loosely be interpreted as country-specific trend inflation
and potential output for the ith country, respectively.
Moreover, the stationary component of output and infla-
tion depends on the common cycle gtthroughasetof
idiosyncratic factor loadings iand iand measurement
errors that feature time-varying variances ehkit.Itisworth
stressing that Equation (2) represents a country-specific
Phillips curve that establishes a relationship between infla-
tion and the area-wide output gap gt. One key goal of this
paper is to assess whether there exists a Phillips curve
across EA countries by inspecting iand functions thereof.
912

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT