Monopolization Issues

Pages127-162
127
CHAPTER VI
MONOPOLIZATION ISSUES
Monopolization is prohibited by Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
1
Mere size is not illegal, however. A violation requires both (1)
possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful
acquisition and maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth
or development resulting from historical accident, business skill, or a
superior product or service.
2
Determining whether a violation has
occurred generally requires a searching fact inquiry under the rule of
reason.
3
In addit ion, to assert a claim private plaintiffs must also
demonstrate that the anticompetitive conduct at issue resulted in an
“antitrust injury,” rather than some other type of harm to the plaintiff.
4
Energy utilities traditionally have been viewed as natural
monopolies, and thus granted the exclusive right to serve a defined
territory subject to regulatory oversight by state utility commissions. So
long as the utility was subject to active state supervision, its conduct
generally was immune from antitrust scrutiny under the state action
immunity doctrine.
5
Deregulation, however, brings with it a
corresponding loss of this protective immunity.
6
As deregulation
progresses, claims of abuse of monopoly power may become
increasingly common, both as a means f or challenging efforts of
1. 15 U.S.C. § 2; Verizon Commc’ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V.
Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004); Elliott Ind us. Ltd. v. BP Am.
Prod. Co., 407 F.3d 1091, 1124 n.30 (10th Cir. 200 5).
2. Trinko, 540 U.S. at 407; City of Moundridge v. Ex xon Mobil Corp., 471
F. Supp. 2d 20 , 41 (D.D.C. 2007); United States v. Grinnell Corp., 384
U.S. 563, 570-71 (1966).
3. United States v. Chi. Bd. of Trade, 246 U.S. 231 (1918).
4. See, e.g., Atl. Richfield Co. v. U SA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 344
(1990).
5. See Chapter III.A for a discussion of state action i mmunity.
6. Of course, so long as the sta te continues actively to supervise the delivery
of electricity pursuant to a clearly articulated state policy to displace
competition, state action imm unity will still apply. See, e.g., Snake River
Valley Elec. Ass’n v. Pac ifiCorp, 357 F.3d 1042, 1049-50 (9th Cir. 2004 )
(defendant electric company’s refusal to wheel was protected by state
action immunity).
128 Energy Antitrust Handbook
traditional suppliers t o retain or expand market share, and for contesting
new arrangements to market energy and energy services.
A. Possession of Monopoly Power in the Relevant Market
Market share often is used as a proxy or first screen to determine if a
party possesses market power. The precise market share required has not
been specified by the Supreme Court, but “lower courts generally require
minimum market share of between 70% and 80%.”
7
A market share
below 50 percent generally is insufficient to establish market power.
8
In
regulated industries, in which an entity’s market share may result f rom
regulation, rather than conduct in the marketplace, some courts have held
that market share is not as good an indicator of market power as in other
industries, and may overstate the ability of a party to control prices and
reduce output.
9
Market share is useful only as a first step in analyzing whether
market power exists. In determining the necessary market share, a court
will examine a series of market characteristics, including the size and
strength of competitors, barriers to entry, the degree of concentration,
profit levels, and whether the market share of the challenged party has
increased in recent times.
10
In the coal industry, for example, to
determine market share and market concentration, courts have examined
7. Colo. Interstate Gas Co. v. Natural Gas Pipeline Co., 885 F.2d 683, 694
n.18 (10th Cir. 1989); see also Metronet Servs. Corp. v. U S West
Commc’ns, 329 F.3d 986, 1003 (9th Cir. 2003) (stating courts generally
require a 65% or greater market share to establish prima facie market
power), vacated on other grounds, 540 U.S. 1147 (2004).
8. See, e.g., United States v. Dentsply Int’l Inc., 399 F.3d 181, 187 (3d Cir.
2005) (absent other pertinent factors, a share significantly larger than
55% has been required to establis h prima facie market power); U.S.
Anchor Mfg. v. Rule Indus., 7 F.3d 986, 1000 (11 th Cir. 1993).
9. Metronet, 329 F.3d at 1003 -04; see also Consol. Gas Co. v. City Gas Co.,
880 F.2d 297, 300 (11th Cir. 1989), reinstated on reh’g, 912 F.2d 1262
(11th Cir. 1990) (en banc) (per curiam), vacated as moot, 499 U.S. 91 5
(1991).
10. Oahu Gas Serv. v. Pac. Res., 838 F.2d 360, 366 (9 th Cir. 1988);
Natsource LLC v. GFI Group Inc., 332 F. Supp. 2d 626, 635 (S.D.N.Y.
2004) (even market shares of 50% are insufficient to deter mine market
power where ot her factors such as low barriers to entry and strong
competition exist).
Monopolization Issues 129
coal reserves, loadout, production, and practical capacities.
11
The
inaccuracies that result from the static market share analysis can be
overcome by looking at other factors affecting the parties’ ability to
collude or exercise market power. For example, in an order on rehearing
in AEP Power Marketing Inc.,
12
the Federal Energy Regulatory
Commission (FERC) established two indicative screens for assessing an
electric generation supplier’s market power when the supplier applies to
be allowed to establish market-based rates. The first, called a pivotal
supplier analysis, focuses on the ability to exercise market power
unilaterally by measuring market power at peak times.
13
The second is
an analysis of the uncommitted market share measuring whether a
supplier has a dominant position in the market on a seasonal basis.
14
Both analyses also consider a supplier’s native load obligations and other
commitments.
15
Market shares must also be viewed in the context of fundamental
changes occurring in the structure of the relevant market. Where, for
example, the structure of an energy market is changing dramatically,
current market shares could overstate market power.
16
A number of factors complicate the determination of relevant
product and geographic markets for monopoly claims in today’s energy
industry. As a result, market definition has been contested vigorously in
such cases. One result of deregulation is that gas pipeline and electric
transmission grid operating functions that previously were viewed as part
of a single product market now may be considered separate markets.
Generation, transmission, and distribution functions, which a single,
vertically integrated utility formerly performed, now may be unbundled.
Companies that previously offered only natural gas or electricity now
may offer both. Companies that offer electricity also may own coal
11. Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Arch Coal, Inc., 32 9 F. Supp. 2d 109, 127-28
(D.D.C. 2004).
12. 107 F.E.R.C. ¶ 61,018, 61,054-55 (2004).
13. Id. at 61,061.
14. Id.
15. Id. at 61,055; see also Wis. Pub. Power Inc. v. Fed. Energy Regulatory
Comm’n, 493 F.3d 239, 251 (D.C. Cir. 2007) (independent electricity
transmission system operator created market power mitigation measures
that reduced seller electricity generators bids if they exceeded certain
“conduct” and “impact” thresholds that were defined in relation to an
estimate of the seller’s marginal costs).
16. See United States v. Gen. Dynamics Corp., 415 U. S. 486, 501 (1974).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT