A Model of Tradeable Capital Tax Permits

AuthorTIMOTHY P. HUBBARD,JUSTIN SVEC
Published date01 December 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12127
Date01 December 2015
AMODEL OF TRADEABLE CAPITAL TAX PERMITS
TIMOTHY P. HUBBARD
Colby College
JUSTIN SVEC
College of the Holy Cross
Abstract
Standard models of horizontal capital tax competition
predict that, in a Nash equilibrium, states set tax rates
inefficiently due to externalities—capital inflow to one state
corresponds to capital outflow for another state.
Researchers often suggest that the federal government
impose Pigouvian taxes to correct for these effects and
achieve efficiency. We propose an alternative incentive-
based regulation: tradeable capital tax permits. Under this
system, the federal government would require a state to
hold a permit if it wanted to reduce its capital income
tax rate from some predefined benchmark. These permits
would be tradeable across states. We show that, if the federal
government sets the correct number of total permits, then
social efficiency is achieved. We discuss the advantages of
this system relative to the canonical suggestion of Pigouvian
taxes.
1. Introduction
One of the key insights in the tax competition literature is that policy compe-
tition across states leads to socially inefficient policy choices. The inefficiency
is due to the presence of externalities, which can be particularly salient when
Timothy P.Hubbard, Department of Economics, Colby College, 5242 Mayflower Hill Drive,
Waterville, ME 04901 (timothy.hubbard@colby.edu). Justin Svec, Department of Eco-
nomics, College of the Holy Cross, Box 45A, Worcester, MA 01610 (jsvec@holycross.edu).
We thank Bryan Engelhardt, Gagan Ghosh, B. Ravikumar,Tom Tietenberg, and David
E. Wildasin for helpful comments. We also appreciate constructive comments from two
anonymous referees, an associate editor, and the editor, John P. Conley, who provided
helpful suggestions which improved the manuscript.
Received June 18, 2014; Accepted June 20, 2014.
C2014 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 17 (6), 2015, pp. 916–942.
916
Tradeable Capital Tax Permits 917
considering a state’s tax rate on a relatively mobile factor like capital. Specif-
ically, if the states are sufficiently similar, then in its competition for scarce
capital, each state has the incentive to cut its capital income tax rate.1This
reduction spurs an inflow of capital, raising wages, total tax revenues, and
public-good provision. A capital inflow toward one state, though, means a
capital outflow from other states. This outflow implies that other states will
confront lower wages, a decreased tax base, and hence lower public-good
provision. These welfare costs to other states are not internalized by the state
considering a decrease in its capital income tax rate. Consequently, from a
social perspective, each state sets an inefficient tax on capital income.
The responses of other states compound the problem: other, similarly-
sized states respond by decreasing their own capital income tax rate, hoping
to prevent the capital outflow. As such, the tax competition literature pre-
dicts a “race to the bottom” in which all states feel obliged to set suboptimally
low tax rates on capital. One implication of this is that states must either
increase other taxes (e.g., labor, consumption, property, etc.) to supplement
lost capital tax revenue or decrease their provision of public goods.
A recent example of this incentive to poach other states’ capital involves
Illinois and Wisconsin. Due to its large debt, Illinois was recently forced to
raise its tax rates on both personal and corporate income. The Wisconsin
governor, Scott Walker, responded to this move, saying “Today we renew that
call to Illinois businesses, ‘Escape to Wisconsin.’ You are welcome here.”2In
support of this sentiment, the Wisconsin State Legislature passed a proposal
that would eliminate the corporate income tax rate for two years for firms
that relocate to Wisconsin from other states.3
In addition to this anecdote, there is evidence of tax competition at all
levels of government. Slemrod (2004) noted that corporate tax rates across
countries began declining in the 1980s and seemed to be converging, facts
that are consistent with tax competition. While his goal was to disentangle
competing arguments for whether this observation is, in fact, evidence of
tax competition, he found measures of openness are negatively associated
with corporate tax rates. Likewise, Devereux, Lockwood, and Redoano
(2008) found evidence of strategic interaction between countries with open
economies and concluded that reductions in tax rates can be explained
almost entirely by more intense competition. Carlsen, Langset, and Rattsø
(2005) used data from Norway to construct a measure of firm mobility and
used it to show that municipalities with high firm mobility tend to have
lower tax levels. Davies (2005) provided evidence that U.S. states compete
1Bucovetsky (1991) shows that if the states are sufficiently asymmetric, the larger state (the
capital importer) would want to raise its tax above the efficient level.
2See http://www.wisgov.state.wi.us/newsroom/press-release/governor-walker-statement-
illinois-tax-increase-wisconsin-open-business.
3See Assembly Bill 3 in the January 2011 Special Session of the State of Wisconsin 2011–
2012 Legislature available at http://legis.wisconsin.gov/2011/data/JR1AB-3.pdf.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT