A model of the optimal allocation of government expenditures

AuthorSimon Fan,Pierre Pestieau,Yu Pang
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12416
Published date01 August 2020
Date01 August 2020
J Public Econ Theory. 2020;22:845876. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
845
Received: 2 October 2018
|
Accepted: 31 October 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12416
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
A model of the optimal allocation of
government expenditures
Simon Fan
1
|
Yu Pang
2
|
Pierre Pestieau
3,4,5
1
Department of Economics, Lingnan
University, Tuen Mun, Hong Kong
2
School of Business, Macau University of
Science and Technology, Taipa, Macau
3
Department of Economics, University of
Liège, Liège, Belgium
4
CORE, LouvainlaNeuve, Belgium
5
Toulouse School of Economics,
Toulouse, France
Correspondence
Yu Pang, School of Business, Macau
University of Science and Technology,
Taipa 999078, Macau.
Email: ypang@must.edu.mo
Abstract
Government expenditures can be used for various socio-
economic objectives, including public education, con-
sumption of public goods and services, and social
protection. This paper analyzes the optimal allocation of
public expenditures among these competing functions. We
establish an overlapping generations model with hetero-
geneous individuals in which the government optimally
chooses income tax, transfer payment, educational spend-
ing, and public consumption. Our model characterizes the
transitional dynamics and the steady state of each function
with and without a payasyougo intergenerational
contract. We also conduct a simulation illustrating that
the presence of an intergenerational contract may raise
public consumption and social welfare in the steady state.
KEYWORDS
government spending, individual heterogeneity, public consumption,
public education
JEL CLASSIFICATION
H20; H31; H50
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Largescale public expenditures are a widespread phenomenon in industrialized economies. In
2016, general government spending amounted to 37.8% of the gross domestic product in the
United States, 39% in Japan, and about 50% in many European countries (OECD, 2018).
Governments massive involvement in market economies serves redistributive, allocative, and
regulatory purposes, which effectively mitigate income inequality, provide public goods and
services, and promote sustainable development (Barr, 1992; Musgrave, 1959). For instance, the
Nordic model, which features a blend of socialist values and free market capitalism, is usually
perceived to have succeeded in advancing equity, efficiency, and wellbeing (Pestieau &
Lefebvre, 2018; Stiglitz, 2015).
Government spending has a variety of socioeconomic objectives. Table 1 lists the government
expenditure breakdown by 10 functions, and reports their percentage shares of total expenditures
in several European countries between 2012 and 2016. In each country, the largest share is
devoted to social protection, mainly in the form of incomeredistribution programs that transfer
wealth to the poor. Schooling is also an important target of public funds: most of these
governments appropriate around 10% of their expenditures to establish and maintain the state
education systems. The other eight functions, including health care, public services, economic
affairs (e.g., infrastructure construction and supply of water and electricity), environmental
protection, and so forth fit generally into the category of consumption of public goods and
services. Public consumption accounts for half of government spending in almost every country.
Based on the classifications used in Table 1, we categorizegovernment expenditures into three
main divisionspublic education, social protection, and consumption of public goods and
services. Educational expenditure provides twobenefits: first, it facilitatesthe formation of human
capital of the future generation, allowing altruistic parents to benefit from their childrens
improved quality; second, it promotes social mobility, which helps lower wage inequality of
future generations. The provision of public goods and services directly enhances peoples welfare.
As economic progress improves the living standard, households want more public consumption,
which is complementary to their private consumption (Ganelli & Tervala, 2009). Transfers to the
poor not only raise social welfare by the law of diminishing marginal utility (e.g., Boadway &
Keen, 2000) but also address the public concern over income inequality and longterm economic
development (De la Croix & Doepke, 2003, 2004; Fleurbaey, 2008, 2009).
To the extent that various categories compete for resources under the fiscal budget
constraint, an intriguing question arises as to how government spending can be optimally
allocated between them? The analysis of the optimal allocation of government spending has
deep roots in economics, going back at least to Samuelson (1954). Existing literature on public
finance concentrates on one or two categories. For example, Docquier, Paddison, and Pestieau
(2007) and Del Rey and LopezGarcia (2013) study the optimal levels of education and pension
provided by a welfaremaximizing government; other studies include Possen and Slutsky
(1980), Meltzer and Richard (1981), Glomm and Ravikumar (1992, 1997), Boadway and
Marchand (1995), Kaganovich and Zilcha (1999), Del Rey and LopezGarcia (2016). This paper
develops a more comprehensive profile covering social protection, public education, public
consumption, and intergenerational mobility.
We establish an overlapping generations model in which the government chooses income taxes/
transfers and expenditures on education and public consumption. In our model, there are two types
of individualsthe skilled and the unskilledwhose income levels are positively related to their
labor skill. Addressing individual heterogeneity allows us to probe into the redistributive function of
government spending. Moreover, an individuals skill plays a vital role in shaping her childrens
quality, as a number of empirical studies have demonstrated that parental background is critical to
an individuals achievement (e.g., Becker, 1991; De la Croix & Michel, 2002). Therefore, even if
individualsnet incomes tend to be equalized after taxes/transfers, the effect of skill heterogeneity
on childrens human capital formation persists.
We start our analysis with the case in which each generation care about their own utility and
do not make any wealth transfer to the previous generation. Our analysisshows that in the steady
state educational expenditure increases with the learning efficiency of skilled workerschildren
and the wage differential but decreases with thefertility rate. Also, under some configuration, the
846
|
FAN ET AL.
TABLE 1 Government expenditure by function (% of total expenditure): 20122016 average
Belgium Denmark France Germany Greece Italy Netherlands Spain UK
Social protection 36.3 43.3 43.0 42.8 37.6 41.7 36.5 38.9 37.9
Education 11.6 12.6 9.6 9.6 8.2 7.9 11.8 9.1 11.6
Health 14.2 15.5 14.2 15.9 9.3 14.1 17.8 13.7 17.3
General public services 15.4 13.7 11.5 14.1 18.6 17.3 10.9 14.9 11.4
Economic affairs 12.7 6.4 9.4 7.2 13.7 8.0 8.9 11.3 7.2
Public order and safety 3.3 1.8 2.9 3.5 3.8 3.8 4.2 4.5 4.6
Defence 1.6 2.2 3.1 2.4 4.4 2.4 2.5 2.1 5.0
Environment protection 1.8 0.8 1.8 1.4 2.7 1.8 3.3 1.9 1.8
Recreation, culture and religion 2.3 3.2 2.4 2.2 1.3 1.5 3.2 2.6 1.7
Community amenities 0.7 0.5 2.1 0.9 0.5 1.4 0.9 1.1 1.6
Source: Eurostat (accessed on July 25, 2018). Government expenditures are decomposed into 10 broad functions based on the classification of the functions of government (COFOG) used in
the European regime of National Accounts (ESA, 2010). Figures are calculated as a simple average based on the available data for the most recent 5 years.
FAN ET AL.
|
847

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT