A model of biased intermediation

Published date01 December 2019
AuthorAlexandre Cornière,Greg Taylor
Date01 December 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1756-2171.12298
RAND Journal of Economics
Vol.50, No. 4, Winter 2019
pp. 854–882
A model of biased intermediation
Alexandre de Corni`
ere
and
Greg Taylor∗∗
We study situations in which consumers rely on a biased intermediary’s advice when choosing
among sellers. We introduce the notion that sellers’ and consumers’ payoffs can be congruent
or conflicting, and show that this has important implications for the effects of bias. Under
congruence, the firm benefiting from bias has an incentive to offer a better deal than its rival
and consumers can be better-off than under no bias. Under conflict, the favored firm offers lower
utility, and bias harms consumers. We study various policies for dealing with bias and show that
their efficacy also depends on whether the payoffs exhibit congruence or conflict.
1. Introduction
Consumers often turn to an intermediary for advice when choosing among firms. The inter-
mediary’sjob is to provide information about which are the best products and which products best
fit each consumer’s needs. However, the intermediary does not necessarily have the consumer’s
best interests in mind. Particular concerns have repeatedly been raised about the fact that a ver-
tically integrated intermediary has a clear incentive to bias its advice in favor of its own product
offerings rather than those of rivals. These concerns have given rise to high-profile investigations
in many markets by regulators and competition authorities, who worry about potentially harmful
effects of bias.
For example, in the current debate about online platform regulation, a major issue is that
of “own-content bias,” that is when a multisided platform that is also present on one side of
the market behaves in such a way as to steer consumers toward its own products or services.
Google, for instance, has been investigated in many jurisdictions for promoting its own products
in search results.1In 2017, the European Commission imposed a 2.42bn fine after Google was
Toulouse School of Economics, Universityof Toulouse Capitole; alexandre.de-corniere@tse-fr.eu.
∗∗University of Oxford; greg.taylor@oii.ox.ac.uk.
This article was previously circulated under the title “Quality Provision in the Presence of a Biased Intermediary.” We
are grateful to Diane Coyle, Jacques Cr´
emer, Serena Drufuca, Mikhail Drugov, Anthony Dukes, P´
eter Es¨
o, Renaud
Foucart, Doh-Shin Jeon, Ben Hermalin, Paul Klemperer,Laurent Lamy, Jon Levin, Meg Meyer,Ines Moreno de Bar reda,
David Myatt, Martin Obradovits, Sander Onderstal, R´
egis Renault, Andrew Rhodes, Michael Riordan, Andre Veiga,
Chengsi Wang,Chris Wilson, Peyton Young,Jidong Zhou, two anonymous referees, and participants at various seminars
and conferences for useful comments and discussions. The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support of
this research by the NET Institute, www.NETinst.org. A. de Corni`
ere acknowledges funding from ANR under grant
ANR-17-EUR-0010 (Investissements d’Avenir program).
1Edelman and Lai (2013) provide evidence that Google’s own-content bias drives more traffic to its affiliate
flight-search service than it would get otherwise.
854 C2019, The RAND Corporation.
DE CORNI `
ERE AND TAYLOR / 855
found guilty of favoring its own comparison shopping website. Before that, the United States
(US) Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the High Court of England and Wales had ruled
against fining Google for related practices.2Other companies may soon face similar charges: the
European Commission recently launched an investigation to determine whether Amazon uses
its dominant position in the e-commerce market to favor its own, private-label sellers.3Some of
Apple’s practices also tend to favor its own services at the expense of competitors (see Kr¨
amer
and Schnurr, 2018, for a thorough discussion). The European Commission, particularly active
when it comes to the issue of platform regulation, recently put forward a proposal to require
platforms to, among other things, be transparent regarding “how they treat their own goods or
services compared to those offered by their professional users.”4This issue may become more
prevalentin the not-too-distant future with the g rowthof the market for virtual assistants, cur rently
dominated by vertically integrated firms like Amazon, Google, and Apple. Forbesalready repor ts
that “Eighty-five percent of Amazon customers select the recommended Amazon product when
voice shopping.”5
The mechanisms of own-content bias mayalso apply to situations where a leading application
or hardware provider (the “intermediary”) chooses one of its own complementary applications as
the default option for consumers: Safari as the default browser for iPhones, Google as the default
search engine for its browser Chrome, etc. Being the default option is a powerful way to foster
usage of a product or service, as the default bias is well documented (Sunstein and Thaler, 2008).
Companies sometimes choose long-term contracts as an alternative to integration: for example,
the technology press reports that heavy bidding forced Google to pay $300 million for the right
to be the default search engine in Mozilla Firefox and $1 billion for similar rights across Apple’s
suite of products.6
The idea that an intermediary might provide biased recommendations because of financial
incentives is, of course, not restricted to the digital economy. Similar concerns have been raised
in the pharmaceutical and financial industries, where doctors and financial advisers sometimes
receive commissions potentially leading them to recommend one treatment/investment over an-
other which would be better suited to their patient/client (Engelberg, Parsons, and Tefft, 2013;
Cookson et al., 2019; Egan, Forthcoming). Default option bias may also apply there, as when a
bank offers its own insurance alongside a loan.
Biased intermediation raises two main concerns: first, are consumers directed towardinferior
or higher priced products or services? Second, does bias distort firms’ incentives in a way that
harms consumers? Even though these concerns are common to the situations described above,
a certain degree of heterogeneity remains as to the institutional or strategic environments. A
key concern in the price comparison website industry, for example, has been the effect of paid
endorsements on final consumer prices. Search engines and websites, by contrast, are mostly free
to access, so that attention in the search bias debate has focused on innovation and investment
decisions rather than on pricing. It is therefore doubtful that the analysis of a particular market
could be transposed directly to another one. We show that, in order to understand the effects
of bias, it is often possible to reduce complex strategic heterogeneity to a simpler problem of
identifying the relationship between firms’ and consumers’ marginal payoffs.This insight allows
2See ec.europa.eu/competition/elojade/isef/case_details.cfm?proc_code=1_39740 for the EC’sdecision, www.ftc.
gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/statement-commission-regarding-googles-search-practices/130103
brillgooglesearchstmt.pdf for the FTC’s one, and www.bailii.org/ew/cases/EWHC/Ch/2016/253.htmlfor the High Court’s
decision in Streetmap.EU Ltd v Google Inc. & Ors (2016); all pages accessed October 12, 2018.
3See www.ft.com/content/a8c78888-bc0f-11e8-8274-55b72926558f, accessed October 12, 2018.
4A summary of the proposal is available at europa.eu/rapid/press-release_IP-18-3372_en.htm, accessed October
12, 2018.
5See www.forbes.com/sites/kirimasters/2018/06/30/amazon-voice-commerce-a-huge-opportunity-for-brands-or-t
oo-early-to-tell/#2080f0a83d43, accessed October 16, 2018.
6See allthingsd.com/20111222/google-will-pay-mozilla-almost-300m-per-year-in-search-deal-besting-microsoft-
and-yahoo/ and www.recode.net/2014/4/16/11625704/marissa-mayers-secret-plan-to-get-apple-to-dump-google-and-def
ault-to, accessed October 12, 2018.
C
The RAND Corporation 2019.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT