Mixed duopoly: Differential game approach

Date01 August 2019
Published date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12372
Received: 20 April 2018
|
Revised: 25 January 2019
|
Accepted: 9 April 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12372
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Mixed duopoly: Differential game approach
Koichi Futagami
1
|
Toshihiro Matsumura
2
|
Kizuku Takao
3
1
Graduate School of Economics, Osaka
University, Toyonaka, Osaka, Japan
2
Institute of Social Science, The
University of Tokyo, Bunkyoku, Hongo,
Tokyo, Japan
3
Department of Economics, Aomori
Public University, Oaza Goushizawa
Aomori City, Aomori, Japan
Correspondence
Kizuku Takao, Department of
Economics, Aomori Public University,
1534 Aza Yamazaki, Oaza Goushizawa
Aomori City, Aomori 0300196, Japan.
Email: kizukutakao@gmail.com
Funding information
Kyoto University, Grant/Award Number:
the Joint Research Program of KIER;
Japan Society for the Promotion of
Science, Grant/Award Numbers:
15H03355, 15H065240, 17K17975,
18K01500
This study formulates a dynamic mixed oligopoly model,
in which a stateowned public firm competes against a
private firm over multiple periods. We adopt a
differential game formulated by Fershtman and Kamien
[Econometrica 55 (1987), pp. 11511164] and investigate
how the dynamic competition affects the optimal
privatization policy. We characterize the openloop
Nash equilibrium (OLNE) and Markovperfect Nash
equilibrium (MPNE). We show that in the MPNE, an
increase in the degree of privatization has a nonmono-
tonic effect on the price, increasing it in a wide range of
parameter spaces, which is in sharp contrast to the
result in the OLNE or static analyses. We also find that
the optimal degree of privatization is higher in the
MPNE than that in the OLNE and static equilibrium.
These results suggest that intertemporal strategic
behavior changes the optimal privatization policy.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
For more than 50 years, we have observed a worldwide wave of privatization of stateowned
public enterprises. Nevertheless, many public enterprises with significant government
ownership are still active in strategic sectors and control large portions of the worlds
resources. According to an Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD) report by Kowalski, Buge, Sztajerowska, and Egeland (2013), over 10% of the largest
2,000 companies are public enterprises with equivalent to approximately 6% of the global
GDP. They are significant players in sectors, such as transportation, telecommunications,
energy, and finance in OECD countries. In planned and transitional economies, such as
China, Russia, and Vietnam, the presence of the public enterprises is further significant
(Wang & Chiou, 2016).
One classical rationale for public enterprises is to prevent private monopolies from
prevailing in natural monopoly markets with significant economies of scale. However, because
of technological improvement, many markets with public enterprises are not always
J Public Econ Theory. 2019;21:771793. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet © 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
|
771
characterized by significant economies of scale. Indeed, a considerable number of public and
private enterprises compete in a wide range of industries (mixed oligopolies).
1
The optimal
privatization policies in these mixed oligopolies have attracted extensive attention from
researchers in fields, such as public economics, financial economics, industrial organization,
and development economics.
2
Specifically, the literature on mixed oligopolies has investigated the optimal privatization policy in
different situations. Matsumura (1998) shows that the optimal degree of privatization is never zero
unless full nationalization leads to a public monopoly. Lin and Matsumura (2012) and Matsumura
and Okamura (2015) find that the optimal degree of privatization increases with the number of
private firms and decreases with the share of foreign ownership in private firms. Matsumura and
Kanda (2005) show that in free entry markets, the optimal degree of privatization is zero when private
competitors are domestic, whereas Cato and Matsumura (2012) find that it is strictly positive when
the private competitors are foreign, increasing with the foreign ownership share in private firms. In
addition, Chen (2017) shows that the optimal degree of privatization is positive even in free entry
markets when privatization improves production efficiency. Fujiwara (2007) shows a nonmonotonic
relationship between the degree of product differentiation and optimal degree of privatization. Cato
and Matsumura (2015) discuss the relationship between the optimal trade and privatization policies,
showing that a higher tariff rate increases the optimal degree of privatization in free entry markets.
Lee, Matsumura, and Sato (2018) show that the optimal degree of privatization depends on the timing
of privatization. However, all these studies use a static model and do not capture the intertemporal
strategic interaction between public and private firms.
3
In this study, we investigate how the intertemporal strategic interaction between a public
firm (hereafter referred to as Firm 1) and private firm (hereafter referred to as Firm 2) affects
the equilibrium outcomes, given the degree of privatization in Firm 1. We also investigate the
optimal privatization policy in the presence of dynamic competition.
To investigate the dynamic competition in a mixed duopoly, we adopt a differential game
formulated by Fershtman and Kamien (1987). Differential game approaches are widely applied
to a number of studies in various fields of economics.
4
They involve two Nash equilibrium
concepts: the openloop Nash equilibrium (OLNE) and the Markovperfect Nash equilibrium
(MPNE).
5
Importantly, the MPNE is subgame perfect and considers the intertemporal strategic
behaviors of agents.
6
The seminal paper of Fershtman and Kamien (1987) characterizes the
OLNE and the MPNE of the Cournot game with a sticky price. The paper reveals that in the
MPNE, firms produce more aggressively with intertemporal strategic substitutability than that
in the static game. Subsequent studies have also shed light on the importance of intertemporal
strategic behavior for various economic problems.
1
Examples include the United States Postal Service, Deutsche Post AG, Areva, NTT, Japan Tobacco (JT), Volkswagen, Renault, Electricite de France, Japan
Postal Bank, Japan Postal Insurance, Korea Development Bank, and Korea Investment Corporation.
2
For examples of mixed oligopolies and recent developments in this field, see Amir and De Feo (2014), Pal and Saha (2014), Amerighi and De Feo (2017), Lin
and Matsumura (2018), and the works cited therein.
3
Sato and Matsumura (2019) investigate a dynamic mixed oligopoly model. However, they investigate a twoperiod model, in which the firstperiod
privatization policy distorts the government objective in the second period and there is no intertemporal strategic interaction between public and private firms.
4
See Long (2010) for a review of the application.
5
The MPNE is often referred to as a feedback (or closedloop) Nash equilibrium.
6
Cabral (2012) points out the importance of considering issues in an area of industrial organization using dynamic models. Note that the OLNE is not subgame
perfect and does not consider the intertemporal strategic behavior of agents. By definition, each player in the OLNE chooses an entire time path for his/her
action at the outset of the gamegiven the entire path strategy chosen by the other player. In contrast, each firm in the MPNE chooses its strategy at each point in
time after observing the value of its payoffrelevant state variables. See Dockner, Jorgensen, Long, and Sorger (2000) for more detailed explanations of
differential games.
772
|
FUTAGAMI ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT