Mixed Duopoly and Environment

AuthorBIBHAS SAHA,RUPAYAN PAL
Published date01 February 2014
Date01 February 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12056
MIXED DUOPOLY AND ENVIRONMENT
RUPAYAN PAL
Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research (IGIDR)
BIBHAS SAHA
University of East Anglia
Abstract
We show under general demand and cost conditions that
in a mixed duopoly with pollution the government can im-
plement the socially optimal outputs and abatements by a
tax-subsidy scheme and keeping the public firm fully public.
The scheme requires taxing outputs and subsidizing abate-
ments at different rates, unlike a pollution tax. Our result
improves on the shortcoming of a pollution tax to imple-
ment the social optimum. We also show that when the pri-
vate firm is partly foreign-owned, the government will adopt
some privatization and will not implement the social opti-
mum, though the social optimum is implementable.
1. Introduction
Generally it is argued that a publicly owned firm tends to pollute more than a
privately owned firm because it produces more than a private firm. So an im-
portant question is whether the firm ownership matters for the performance
of environmental policies. A number of papers have studied the effects of
a pollution tax in the presence of a public firm (Barcena-Ruiz and Garzon
2006; Beladi and Chao 2006;Cato2008; Naito and Ogawa 2009;Wangand
Wang 2009; Wang, Wang, and Zhao 2009;Saha2012). In a mixed duopoly,
which involves one public firm and one private firm, a pollution tax curbs
the private firm’s output and pollution, but encourages the public firm to
produce more (via strategic effects) and in turn pollute more. Therefore,
Rupayan Pal, Indira Gandhi Institute of Development Research (IGIDR), Film City Road,
Gen. A. K. Vaidya Marg, Goregaon (East), Mumbai 400065, India (rupayan@igidr.ac.in).
Bibhas Saha, School of Economics, University of East Anglia, Norwich NR4 7TJ, United
Kingdom (b.saha@uea.ac.uk).
We gratefully acknowledge helpful comments from two anonymousreferees. Remaining
errors, if any, are our responsibility.
Received January 27, 2011; Accepted February 16, 2012.
C2013 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Journal of Public Economic Theory, 16 (1), 2014, pp. 96–118.
96
Mixed Duopoly and Environment 97
when the government can choose the degree of public ownership along with
the pollution tax, it would partially privatize the public firm to restrain its
incentive to pollute. Moreover, it is known that the optimal pollution tax will
not bring the pollution down to the socially optimal level if pollution abate-
ment is technologically feasible (Barcena-Ruiz and Garzon 2006;Wangand
Wang 2009).
By and large, this body of work has strengthened a negative perception
of public ownership that has been a feature of this literature since deFraja
and Delbono (1989) and Matsumura (1998). One might wonder why public
ownership can be an impediment to social optimality, especially in a model
of externality. Perhaps one should examine what policies can implement the
social optimum, rather than examining what a given policy can do. We try to
take this approach and also overcome some of the limitations of the existing
literature.
We allow the demand and cost functions to be fairly general and permit
asymmetry between firms, unlike most of the previous work. At the same time
we make the policy space slightly larger; to be more specific, we allow the tax
on the output and the subsidy on the abatement to be two independent
instruments. This is a more general approach than relying on a pollution
tax, which penalizes outputs and rewards abatements at the same rate.
Abatement in this literature is assumed to be a clean-up operation per-
formed alongside production. An example would be a paper mill that re-
leases effluents which need to be treated to minimize adverse environmental
impacts (such as eutrophication of water). See Collins and Harris (2002)for
abatement in the UK metal manufacturing industry and Schneider, Lazarus,
and Kollmuss (2010) for nitrous oxide abatements in adipic acid plants glob-
ally. However, in certain industries, such as oil extraction or chemical pesti-
cides, accidents can cause large damages.1Clean-up of such accidental pol-
lution is not the subject matter of our study, though we comment on it later;
see Shavell (2010) and van ’t Veld and Hutchinson (2009) for legal reme-
dies and policy options for such problems. We should stress that the envi-
ronmental economics literature have studied a wider set of policies ranging
from taxes and pollution standards to tradeable emission permits in various
market settings, but not in the context of mixed oligopoly; see Lehmann
(2012) for a survey of policies and also Silva and Zhu (2009), Bhattacharya
and Pal (2010), and Colla, Germain, and Van-Steenberghe (2012).
The social optimum in our setup must be realized in two dimensions—
output and abatement. Each firm’s output should equate the price with
the social marginal cost of production and its abatement should equate the
marginal abatement cost with the marginal damage to the environment. Our
key result is that the social optimum is achievable by a combination of full
1Examples are the 1984 Union Carbide explosion in Bhopal, India resulting in the loss of
25,000 lives and the 2010 British Petroleum (BP) disaster at its Deep-water Horizon oil rig,
theGulfofMexico.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT