Middle Class Without a Net: Savings, Financial Fragility, and Preferences Over Social Insurance
Author | Jacob Gerner Hariri,Amalie Sofie Jensen,David Dreyer Lassen |
DOI | 10.1177/0010414019879718 |
Published date | 01 May 2020 |
Date | 01 May 2020 |
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414019879718
Comparative Political Studies
2020, Vol. 53(6) 892 –922
© The Author(s) 2019
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0010414019879718
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Article
Middle Class Without a
Net: Savings, Financial
Fragility, and Preferences
Over Social Insurance
Jacob Gerner Hariri1, Amalie Sofie Jensen2,
and David Dreyer Lassen1
Abstract
In this article, we show that it is crucial to distinguish between liquid and
illiquid wealth to understand how voters form preferences toward social
insurance. Many households are financially fragile despite having high
incomes and wealth, because they hold little liquid savings. We hypothesize,
and show empirically, that this implies that a substantial group of voters
show strong support for social insurance policies despite being wealthy and
having high incomes, because of their limited ability to self-insure through
own savings in case of an income shock. Our empirical analysis is based on
a novel dataset from Denmark, which combines administrative data with
high-quality measures of individual financial assets and survey measures of
political preferences. Using data for other countries from the European
Social Survey, we find evidence that our results hold more generally and are
not specific to the Danish context.
Keywords
political economy, social welfare programs, public opinion
1University of Copenhagen, Denmark
2Princeton University, Princeon, USA
Corresponding Author:
David Dreyer Lassen, Department of Economics and CEBI, University of Copenhagen, Øster
Farimagsgade 5, 1353 Copenhagen, Denmark.
Email: ddl@econ.ku.dk
879718CPSXXX10.1177/0010414019879718Comparative Political StudiesHariri et al.
research-article2019
Hariri et al. 893
Introduction
Social insurance and redistribution are defining features of the welfare state,
and a vast literature in political economy investigates the individual-level
determinants of social policy preferences. Recent work has emphasized the
importance of economic self-interest, including portability of skills (Iversen
& Soskice, 2001), labor market risk (Rehm, 2009), wealth holdings (Ansell,
2014), and economic worries more generally (Hacker, Rehm, & Schlesinger,
2013), for understanding political preference formation. However, the focus
on formal social insurance arrangements is incomplete—and recognized as
such: In an influential analysis of social insurance and redistribution, Moene
and Wallerstein (2001, p. 871) note that “[t]heoretically, the largest gap in our
approach is the absence of a private alternative to publicly provided insur-
ance. We have concentrated on the loss of income, a risk that cannot be
insured privately.” But private supplements and alternatives to social insur-
ance of income risks do exist, partly because formal social insurance pro-
grams often offer only partial income replacement and, in the case of
unemployment insurance (UI), only for a limited time. Therefore, people’s
reliance on formal social insurance is in practice widely supplemented by,
and sometimes secondary to, informal self-insurance, of which the most
important component is drawing on private savings (Gruber, 2001).
Yet, the availability of private savings and credit market opportunities dif-
fer considerably across individuals. The middle class is now becoming more
financially fragile (Lusardi, Schneider, & Tufano, 2011) and heterogeneous
(Atkinson & Brandolini, 2011). Many households with medium or high
incomes are increasingly characterized by limited savings and accumulated
debts, which leaves them “no margin for error in their financial lives”
(Sullivan, Warren, & Westbrook, 2000, p. 250). Across industrialized coun-
tries, wealthy “hand-to-mouth” households—households that have positive
illiquid wealth, typically from housing equity, but little or no liquid savings—
constitute between 30% and 40% of the population (Kaplan, Violante, &
Weidner, 2014). One consequence of this is that economic vulnerability, mea-
sured by a lack of access to economic buffers, is also common among mid-
dle-class and rich households and, thus, largely unrelated to current income.
Following the literature on the economics of consumption and savings, we
refer to people who are unable to access economic buffers to maintain current
consumption as liquidity constrained.
In this article, we examine whether the presence of such liquidity con-
straints increases individual-level demand for social insurance and redistribu-
tion. Liquidity constraints is a core concept in economic theory, necessary to
understand the link from current income to consumption. By introducing it
Get this document and AI-powered insights with a free trial of vLex and Vincent AI
Get Started for FreeStart Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting

Start Your 3-day Free Trial of vLex and Vincent AI, Your Precision-Engineered Legal Assistant
-
Access comprehensive legal content with no limitations across vLex's unparalleled global legal database
-
Build stronger arguments with verified citations and CERT citator that tracks case history and precedential strength
-
Transform your legal research from hours to minutes with Vincent AI's intelligent search and analysis capabilities
-
Elevate your practice by focusing your expertise where it matters most while Vincent handles the heavy lifting
