A Microeconomic Framework for Evaluating Energy Efficiency Rebound and Some Implications.

AuthorBorenstein, Severin

INTRODUCTION

In policy discussions of combating climate change, the most cost-effective response is often said to be energy efficiency: improving devices to provide the same services using less energy, and thus causing fewer greenhouse gas emissions. The impact of energy efficiency on total energy use is controversial, however, because reducing the energy that a device consumes generally lowers the marginal cost of using the device and may raise the wealth of consumers and producers. Thus, an energy efficiency improvement can lead to greater use of the energy efficient device and increased spending on other goods that were previously not affordable. This phenomenon is known as "rebound" or "takeback" in the energy efficiency literature.

Because rebound is a reoptimization in response to price and income changes, in standard economic analysis it would be seen as welfare enhancing. Nonetheless, in measuring the energy savings from an efficiency upgrade, rebound is an offset to the direct measurement of energy saved from a device providing the same services using less energy. The extent of rebound is the subject of hot debate and has lead to a wide variety of views on the role that energy efficiency can play in addressing climate change.

A great deal has been written on the rebound effect, but much of it seems to be either too narrowly focused--covering just the increased use of the good that has become more energy efficient--or makes claims much broader than the evidence can support--attributing most increases in societal energy consumption over time to the correlation of energy use and increased efficiency of its use. In this paper, I venture to provide a microeconomic framework that effectively captures the energy consumption effects that result from an energy efficiency improvement.

My focus here is on quantitative measurement of energy efficiency rebound and the net energy saved. This is not an analysis of the welfare benefits of energy efficiency and rebound, which is itself an important topic, but distinct from the quantity measurement issue. The quantitative rebound issue is obviously not the whole story, but it is a primary focus of debates about energy efficiency. (1) Research measuring rebound comes to widely divergent conclusions about both the appropriate measurement method and the implied size of rebound. (2)

I focus on the microeconomics of rebound following an energy efficiency upgrade at the end-use consumer level. This differs from much of the rebound literature in that I do not focus on producer-side energy efficiency and do not use a production function (or cost function, the dual) approach to analyzing the behavioral response to an improvement in energy efficiency. Instead, I disaggregate the impact of an end-user energy efficiency upgrade using microeconomic tools that permit a more broad and rigorous analysis than I have found in the existing literature. This approach yields significant insights into the overall impact of end-use energy efficiency improvements. The approach I take has the potential weakness of falling into a fallacy of composition when extrapolated to the whole economy--inferring an aggregate effect by scaling up the effect from a microeconomic level--though I attempt to address this concern.

After a very brief review of the economic research on rebound in section I, section II presents a model of the change in consumption choices in the presence of an energy efficiency improvement, recognizing the consumer's budget constraint. I show how this approach can help to parse the rebound effect into income and substitution effects and that the income and substitution effects operate independently. Section III addresses many other factors that are raised in studies of rebound--such as time constraints on consumption and responsiveness of supply and innovation--and discusses how they fit into the framework. Section IV uses the framework to do back-of-the-envelope calculations of rebound and illustrates the approach with examples from auto fuel efficiency and lighting power usage. I conclude and suggest next steps in section V.

  1. A VERY BRIEF HISTORY OF REBOUND ANALYSIS

    There is a surprisingly large literature on energy efficiency rebound. Numerous papers have reviewed this literature, with Greening, Greene and Difiglio (2000) being the most widely referenced, and more recent contributions from Sorrell (2009), Jenkins, Nordhaus and Shellenberger (2011), and Azevedo, Sonnberger, Thomas, Morgan, and Renn (2012). I do not attempt to present such a review here, but do use those overviews to place my analysis within the literature.

    While the first contribution is attributed to Jevons (1865), the field is generally considered to have lain dormant until revived by Khazzoom (1980) and Brookes (1990, 1992, 1993). One strain of the literature is theoretical and simulation-based analyses of the implications of different macroeconomic growth models, and accompanying debate about which functional forms for production can potentially yield rebound in excess of 100% (known as "backfire").

    This paper contributes to the microeconomic literature on rebound. These analyses start from an energy efficiency improvement of a single actor or sector in the economy, though many still incorporate economy-wide implications. Khazzoom (1980) takes this perspective. My contribution here is most closely related to the works of Binswanger (2000), Berkhout, Muskens and Velthuijsen (2000) and, more recently, Thomas and Azevedo (2013), in that they use a standard microeconomic frame and decompose energy use changes from an energy efficiency upgrade into income and substitution effects. Implicitly, at least, they also suggest that the substitution effect must include a reduction in consumption of some other good in order to increase consumption of a good as it becomes more energy efficient. I contribute to this literature by extending the theoretical discussion and by recognizing some implications of the framework that seem to have been previously overlooked. In particular, I show that non-marginal cost pricing, which is commonplace in utility pricing, can greatly change rebound due to income effects. I also discuss the implications of income and substitution effects when sub-optimizing behavior yields an "energy efficiency gap," which is generally defined as neglected opportunities for individuals (or companies) to save money by improving energy efficiency.

  2. BASIC MODEL

    An individual consumes an appliance service in quantity q0 at a marginal price of per unit of service. (3) For now, all goods in the economy are produced in perfectly competitive markets, so price reflects the marginal cost of production. Below, I consider non-marginal-cost pricing. I assume the consumer already owns the appliance and, for now, that her elasticity of the number (or type) of appliances she buys with respect to the marginal price is zero. (4) She also consumes a set of N other goods in quantities [q.sub.1]. . . [q.sub.N] at prices [p.sub.1]. . . [p.sub.N].

    To simplify notation, I compress all lifetime consumption into one period, implicitly assuming that the nominal and real interest rate is zero. The NPV of the consumer's lifetime income is I, so the lifetime balanced budget constraint is

    [mathematical expression not reproducible]

    The goods also have embodied (or life-cycle) energy consumption per unit, e0 for the appliance service and [e.sub.n] for each of the other N goods, (5) such that total energy use is

    [mathematical expression not reproducible]

    The individual has an income elasticity of demand for each good such that all change of income is absorbed in changes of consumption of these goods, [mathematical expression not reproducible]. Define EI as the associated change in the individual's total energy use when she adjusts consumption to a change in income,

    [mathematical expression not reproducible]

    There is an upgrade, U, to the appliance that reduces its energy use and cost per unit of service without otherwise changing its service attributes. U has a cost of [p.sub.U] and the upgrade itself has embodied energy [e.sub.U]. The improvement is a binary choice, not a continuous variable. If the improvement is made, [p.sub.0] is reduced to [p.sub.0] and [e.sub.0] is reduced to [e.sub.0].

    If the consumer makes the investment in U and lowers [p.sub.0], then even if the compensated price elasticity of demand for the appliance service is zero, the investment will change the consumer's lifetime income available to spend on goods by [DELTA]I = [q.sub.0]([p.sub.0]-[p.sub.0])-[p.sub.U] . As a result consumption of each good n will change by [mathematical expression not reproducible].

    In addition, if the change from [p.sub.0] to [p.sub.0] causes the consumer to increase consumption of the appliance service, then she will substitute away from other goods as she moves along the compensated demand curve for the appliance service. As a result, even if there is no income change (i.e., [q.sub.0] ( [p.sub.0] -[p.sub.0] ) = pU) consumption of each good n will change by

    [mathematical expression not reproducible]

    such that

    [mathematical expression not reproducible]

    in order to maintain the budget constraint, where dc designates the compensated (or Hicksian) demand derivative. (6)

    Separating the income and substitution effects on consumption of both the appliance and all other goods, the change in energy consumption can then be written to correspond closely to standard discussions of rebound.

    [mathematical expression not reproducible] (1)

    6. Because the change in [p.sub.0] is discrete, not marginal, this use of income and substitution effects differs slightly from the standard economic usage. Since my focus is on consumption quantities rather than welfare, however, this slightly nonstandard terminology serves to simplify notation rather than confuse welfare analysis.

    The first term in [1] is the static energy efficiency effect, the...

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT