Microcredit, Labor, and Poverty Impacts in Urban Mexico

Date01 November 2013
Published date01 November 2013
AuthorMiguel Niño‐Zarazúa
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12063
Microcredit, Labor, and Poverty Impacts in
Urban Mexico
Miguel Niño-Zarazúa*
Abstract
Improved household accessibility to credit is a significant determinant of intra-household allocation of
labor resources with important implications for productivity, income, and poverty status. However, credit
accessibility could also have wider impacts on poverty if it leads to new hires outside the household. This
paper contributes to the existing literature on microcredit in two important ways. First, it investigates the
routes through which microcredit reaches those in poverty outside the household. We test whether by
lending to the vulnerable non-poor microcredit can indirectly benefit poor laborers through increased
employment. Second, we conduct the study in the context of urban poverty Mexico. This is relevant when
considering that labor often represents the only source of livelihoods to the extreme urban poor. Our find-
ings point to significant trickle-down effects of microcredit that benefit poor laborers; however, these
effects are only observed after loan-supported enterprising households achieve earnings well above the
poverty line.
1. Introduction
It is now widely understood that credit markets ration loans to those in poverty. In
developing countries in particular, credit markets suffer from informational asym-
metries, which raise the need for collateral and therefore exclude those with low
capital endowments. Caskey et al. (2006), for instance, report that about two thirds
of low-income households living in the Metropolitan area of Mexico City were
“unbanked”, and among those “anked”, only a small percentage had access to credit.
Credit rationing implies that households in poverty are not able to allocate their labor
resources optimally. In this context, the improved availability of credit to these groups
should lead to a re-allocation of their labor resources, with implications for their
productivity, income, and poverty status.
The improved access to credit could in addition have a wider impact on poverty if it
leads to new hires among fully or partially unemployed workers outside the loan-
supported household. The existing literature on microcredit, which focuses mostly on
rural areas, suggests that this wider impact on poverty through new hires is likely to
be small at best, partly because of labor-market rigidities. Khandker (1998) for
instance, finds in the context of rural Bangladesh, an increase in self-employment as
result of household participation in microcredit programmes, although most income-
generating activities rarely involved workers outside the household. Dasgupta and
Ray (1986) suggest that this is partly because at low levels of income, enterprising
* Niño-Zarazúa: World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER),
Katajanokanlaituri 6B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland. Tel: +358-9-615-99220; Fax: +358-9-615-99333; E-mail:
Miguel@wider.unu.edu. I want to thank Paul Mosley, Armando Barrientos, Malcolm Harper, Karl Taylor
and Jenny Roberts and seminar participants at the Universities of Sheffield, Manchester, and Stockholm
for valuable comments on previous versions of this paper. Special thanks are due to Fincomun, CAME, and
Promujer-Mexico for their support throughout data collection. I wish to acknowledge financial support
from the National Council of Science and Technology of Mexico. All the errors are mine.
Review of Development Economics, 17(4), 747–762, 2013
DOI:10.1111/rode.12063
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
households can only afford to employ unskilled and malnourished laborers with very
low productivity. Informational constraints regarding the productivity of potential
hires may also prevent enterprising households from hiring labor, with self-
employment perceived as the less risky choice. However, if a household reaches the
upper limit of its available labor supply, then new hires can emerge as a strong alter-
native for production, with implications for the poverty status of poor laborers.
Mosley and Rock (2004) report significant impacts on poor laborers employed by
loan-supported enterprising households, members of microcredit programs operating
in Africa. The extent to which microcredit leads to increased employment among the
extreme urban poor is crucial, especially as labor often represents the only source of
livelihoods for this group.
This paper explores this issue employing quasi-experimental data collected from
three microcredit programs operating in Mexico. The study contributes to the litera-
ture on microcredit impacts in two important respects. First, the study focuses on the
spatial dimension of urban poverty. This is critical when considering that, unlike in
rural markets; labor often represents the only source of earnings for the extreme
poor. We exploit the spatial dimension to deal with endogeneity problems in the
econometric estimation procedure presented below. Second, we investigate the routes
through which microcredit reaches those in extreme poverty outside the household.
We test whether, by lending to non-poor enterprising households, microcredit organi-
zations can indirectly benefit poor laborers through increased employment.
2. Microcredit and Labor Supply
As a starting point for the examination of the relationship between microcredit and
labor supply, it is useful to consider, for expositional purposes, the hypothetical case
of an enterprising household engaging in an income generating activity to produce a
market good y, based on a Cobb–Douglas type production function, y=f(L,K)α,
where Land Kare the quantity of labor and capital, respectively, and αis a param-
eter of production technology. As pointed out by Pitt and Khandker (1996), it is very
unlikely that at the bottom-end of the income distribution technology changes, at
least in the short-term, so αis assumed to be constant.
In the production of y, the enterprising household is assumed to supply the
amount of labor Lh, constrained to the number of household members of working-
age, i. This is defined as LNi
H
ih h=
()
[]
Max
,, implying that under self-employment,
labor supply equals the maximum number of hours worked, h, contributed by
household members of working-age. If production technology does not change, an
injection of capital from microcredit will increase production through household-
level labor supply up to Lh, the point at which the allocation of labor resources is
maximized. Through this mechanism, microcredit is reported to have a positive
impacts on self-employment (Khandker, 1998; McKernan, 2002). However, if more
labor is required for production, then hiring laborers outside the household may
become a sensible choice. New hires are not only a function of household earnings
from production but also of the cost of hiring efficient labor. Leibenstein (1957),
Mazumdar (1959), and Dasgupta (1993) have pointed out that labor efficiency is
conditional upon factors such as nutritional status, individual abilities, skills and
efforts that determine labor productivity. Dasgupta and Ray (1986) have also shown
that at low levels of household earnings, non-poor enterprising households that are
considering employing laborers as a result of having reached their upper limit of
labor supply could find that they can only afford to employ workers with very low
748 Miguel Niño-Zarazúa
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT