Mergers and acquisitions & trade: A global value chain analysis

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12882
Published date01 March 2020
AuthorFederico Carril‐Caccia,Elena Pavlova
Date01 March 2020
586
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/twec World Econ. 2020;43:586–614.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
DOI: 10.1111/twec.12882
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Mergers and acquisitions & trade: A global value
chain analysis*
FedericoCarril-Caccia1,2
|
ElenaPavlova3
1Departamento de Teoría e Historia Económica, Universidad de Granada, Granada, Spain
2Departamento de Análisis Económico y Economía Política, Universidad de Sevilla, Sevilla, Spain
3Euro Area External Sector & Euro Adoption Division, European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany
Funding information
This work was supported by Generalitat Valenciana [GV/2017/052]; Junta de Andalucí [SEJ 340]; and PhD Traineeship from
the European Central Bank.
KEYWORDS
global value chains, gravity model, M&As, trade in value added, trade openness
1
|
INTRODUCTION
During the past 30years, multinational enterprises (MNEs) accelerated the relocation of their produc-
tive activities. Between 1988 and 2016, foreign direct investment (FDI) grew sharply, evolving from
8.2% of the world's GDP to 35.1%.1 This phenomenon made central the concept of global value chains
(GVCs), which refers to the fragmentation across border of different production processes often set by
MNEs through FDI (Amador & Cabral, 2016). Trade in intermediate goods between MNEs' affiliates
or between MNEs and their partners hence represents an increasing share of international trade (Antras
& Yeaple, 2014). As a matter of fact, currently, intermediate goods account for nearly 44% of trade in
goods (UNCTAD, 2017a), and MNEs control approximately 80% of the world's trade (UNCTAD,
2013).
At the same time, increasingly ambitious trade agreements have been negotiated, while we have
also witnessed a surge in protectionist ideas. Recent examples of the former is the signature of the
African Continental Free Trade Area or the Free Trade Agreement (FTA) between the European
Union (EU) and Japan, while the Brexit vote or Trump's increase in tariffs on steel and aluminium
imports stand as good examples of the latter.
Trade policies may not only have a direct effect on trade flows but also influence MNEs' invest-
ment decisions. Initially, FDI and trade can be considered as substitutes: horizontal FDI is expected
1 UNCTAD's statistics on FDI stock over GDP.
*The information and views set out in this publication are those of the authors and do not reflect the views of the institutions
they are affiliated with.
|
587
CARRIL-CACCIA And PAVLOVA
to be driven by increasing trade costs and lower foreign competition (Horstmann & Markusen, 1987).
However, FDI and trade may be complementary. In this case, decreasing trade costs and trade open-
ness are expected to foster vertical capital inflows, export support and export platform FDI (Ekholm,
Forslid, & Markusen, 2007; Hanson, Mataloni, & Slaughter, 2005; Krautheim, 2013). Through these
FDI strategies, MNEs slice up the value chain across borders by setting subsidiaries that engage in
specific economic activities (Krugman, Cooper, & Srinivasan, 1995).
Despite the growing role of GVCs in the world's production since the beginning of the 1990s
(Timmer, Erumban, Los, Stehrer, & Vries, 2014), the existing evidence on the nexus between FDI and
host countries' trade openness is still ambiguous. Some studies find a positive relationship (Ramasamy
& Yeung, 2010), while others report a nonsignificant (Kolstad & Villanger, 2008) or negative con-
nection (Wheeler & Mody, 1992). Since FDI could potentially favour, for instance, economic growth
or productivity (Alfaro, Chanda, Kalemli-Ozcan, & Sayek, 2004; Ashraf, Herzer, & Nunnenkamp,
2016), and countries' trade characteristics can be shaped through economic policy, it is relevant to
further explore the nexus between FDI and trade.
The ambiguity in the results may be explained by the fact that the indicators commonly used to
reflect trade openness, such as gross trade over GDP, give a poor insight into countries' trade char-
acteristics and policy. FDI strategies which are positively linked with trade might not be necessarily
attracted by trade openness per se, but by some specific involvements in trade and GVCs. For instance,
the capacity of producing intermediates goods which are later used in the production process in other
countries can favour vertical FDI (Beugelsdijk, Pedersen, & Petersen, 2009; Braconier, Norback, &
Urban, 2005). Alternatively, economies which can export goods to a wider number of countries are
more likely to attract export platform FDI (Medvedev, 2012). Additionally, trade openness may also
represent a higher level of foreign competition that would deter FDI (Wheeler & Mody, 1992). Trade
openness indicators might be positively related with these dimensions but do not allow us to disentan-
gle the relevance of each of these factors.
We extend the previous literature by accounting for the value added embedded in trade,2 the degree
of heterogeneity of exports destinations and imports sources, for both final and intermediate goods
and services, and the position and the degree of participation in GVC. These indicators are closely
linked with the FDI strategies described above that result in the international fragmentation of produc-
tion. The capacity of exporting to a wider number of countries is linked with the export platform FDI
hypothesis. In addition, the heterogeneity of destinations for intermediate goods exports is also related
with vertical FDI. In particular, if MNEs aim at incorporating firms located in countries that are spe-
cialised in the production of intermediates to be exported to only a few productive sites, or if MNEs
seek acquiring productive sites which provide inputs to several different production facilities accross
the globe. Alternatively, higher competition brought by imports from numerous countries entails
lower expected profits, allowing us to test whether foreign competition through trade deters FDI. The
GVC participation and position indexes represent the degree in which and how gross exports incorpo-
rate domestic and foreign value added (Martinez-Galan & Fontoura, 2019), offering further insight on
the relationship between FDI and the fragmentation of production across borders.
Another empirical concern comes from the fact that most of the previous studies deal with aggre-
gated inward FDI, overlooking the heterogeneity of sources.3 This is a limitation, since investment
2 Trade in value added statistics are retrieved from the World Input-Output Database (WIOD). The WIOD allows us to
unravel the value added embedded in trade and the flows which are consequence of two-way intermediate goods exchange.
Subtracting the pure double-counted flows from gross trade statistics gives a more precise measure of countries' trade
openness and links with the rest of the world.
3 See for example Asiedu (2002), Aizenman and Noy (2006), Botrić and Škuflić (2006), Chakrabarti (2001), Ramasamy and
Yeung (2010) and Teixeira et al. (2017).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT