Medicaid and long‐term care: The effects of penalizing strategic asset transfers

Date01 March 2021
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12307
AuthorAnita Mukherjee,Junhao Liu
Published date01 March 2021
J Risk Insur. 2021;88:5377. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/JORI
|
53
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12307
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Medicaid and longterm care: The effects
of penalizing strategic asset transfers
Junhao Liu
1
|Anita Mukherjee
2
1
Discipline of Finance, The University of
Sydney Business School, The University
of Sydney, NSW, Australia
2
Department of Risk and Insurance,
Wisconsin School of Business, University
of WisconsinMadison, WI, USA
Abstract
Medicaid provides a critical source of insurance for long
term care, and individuals may strategically offload as-
sets (typically to children) to meet the meanstested
eligibility requirement. In this article, we quantify the
extent of such behavior using variation in the penalty for
improper parenttochild transfers induced by the Deficit
Reduction Act of 2005. We estimate differencein
differences models based on the hypothesis that only
individuals with high levels of nursing home risk (high
risk) will alter transfers because of the Act. We find that
over a 2year horizon, highrisk individuals reduced
transferstochildrenontheextensivemarginby
11 percent and that the average total amount of transfers
decreased by $4,860. The results hold only for
coupled respondents. We also conduct a triple
differences analysis to examine heterogeneity with fi-
nancial literacy and find that even those with a low level
of financial literacy responded to the penalty.
KEYWORDS
Financial literacy, intergenerational transfers, longterm care,
medicaid, social insurance
1|INTRODUCTION
Medicaid is the largest meanstested health insurance program in the United States and pro-
vides a key source of nursing home coverage for older Americans. Current program
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
© 2020 American Risk and Insurance Association
expenditures are about $500 billion each year, of which 30 percent goes to nursing home and
other longterm care services (CMS, 2017).
As with any meanstested program, there is a concern about Medicaid planning,that
individuals strategically adjust their asset holdings to meet eligibility requirements. Since many
types of asset transfers are not easily detectable, understanding the extent of such strategic
behavior is crucial for policy making, especially in an era of Medicaid reform and rising costs of
the program (Harrington, 2010). While there has been evidence of such behavior in other social
insurance programs, the evidence on Medicaid has been limited and often based on anecdotes
(GAO, 2005).
Yet, it is difficult to ignore the prevalence of Medicaid planning.There is an industry of
elder law experts dedicated to providing such counsel, and the topic has received attention in
the news (New York Times,2017) and in bookstands: for example, Heiser (2006) writes about
Medicaid secretsto avoid nursing home care costs. It seems clear that at least some portion of
the population engages in Medicaid planning, but the extent to which such behaviors inflate
Medicaid costs is unknown. For context, recent research estimates that over half of people aged
5761 will require nursing home care in their lifetimes, though only about onethird will pay for
it outofpocket (Hurd, Michaud, and Rohwedder, 2017).
In this article, we offer new evidence on whether individuals strategically offload assets to become
Medicaid eligible. We do this by leveraging variation in penalties associated with such behaviors
brought about by the Deficit Reduction Act (DRA) of 2005. Signed into law in February 2006 by
President George W. Bush, the DRA attempted to reduce improperfinancial transfers with two new
rules. First, the lookback period on asset transfers increased from 3 to 5 years, meaning that transfers
made over a longer period of time were counted towards one's countable holdings. Second, the DRA
shifted the starting point of the penalty period from the time of improper transfer to the time of
Medicaid application, generating a greater disincentive to engage in such transfers. Together, these
penalties made it more difficult for individuals to spend downfor Medicaid eligibility.
The empirical challenge in assessing the DRA's impact is that since it was enacted na-
tionwide in February 2006, at first glance the policy only enables a beforeandafter analysis.
Such analysis can be difficult to interpret due to the confounding effect of general time trends in
asset holding behaviors. As such, we adopt a differenceindifferences (DD) technique lever-
aging variation from survey data: we use the respondent's selfassessed likelihood of requiring
nursing home care as a proxy for treatment. Specifically, we hypothesize that individuals with
high nursing home risk would alter their asset holdings in response to the DRA, while people
with zero or low nursing home risk should form a useful control group by remaining un-
affected. Directionally, if the DRA is effective at limiting strategic asset transfers, we expect that
individuals facing high nursing home risk will reduce transfer activities.
We examine parenttochild financial transfers as our key outcome. These transfers are
easily made and difficult to detect, making them an ideal way to reduce or shield assets if that is
one's goal. Using our DD framework, we find that the DRA caused individuals with high levels
of anticipated nursing home risk to reduce financial transfers to children on both the extensive
and intensive margins. These effects are statistically significant and economically meaningful:
we estimate a 4 percent decrease in the probability of making any transfer and a $4,860 total
decrease in the average amount of transfers (though most of this is explained by the extensive
margin response). These results correspond to effect sizes of 11 and 90 percent, respectively.
Our findings thus show that the DRA served to reduce strategic transfers from parents to
children, as intended. The results hold only for coupled (married) respondents, potentially due
to their greater incentive to preserve assets for the spouse not seeking Medicaid coverage.
54
|
LIU AND MUKHERJEE

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT