Measuring the Impact of Trade Protection on Industrial Production Size

Published date01 May 2014
AuthorWei Tian,Miaojie Yu
Date01 May 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12081
Measuring the Impact of Trade Protection on
Industrial Production Size
Wei Tian and Miaojie Yu*
Abstract
Trade theory has no clear prediction on how import protection affects an importing sector’s relative size. In
this paper, we estimate the impact of US trade protection on industrial production relative size based on a
translog GDP functional system. Using an industrial panel data set and controlling for factor endowments
and technology improvement, we f‌ind empirical evidence that trade protection does not help much increase
a sector’s relative size. Such f‌indings are also robust to both the inclusion of the role of political economy
and the coverage of various non-tariff measures as proxies of industrial protection.
1. Introduction
When a government imposes an instrument of trade policy on its imports, it has a
direct impact on both producers and consumers. An import tariff on a small country
pushes up its domestic import price which in turn leads to higher domestic production
and less consumption on the import. Without a doubt, a very small country bears a
deadweight loss owing to both production and consumption distortions. In contrast, a
large country might improve its national welfare owing to extra gains from terms of
trade. This is because the terms of trade, its world relative price of exports relative to
imports, would increase as a result of the change of the relative demand and supply of
the import. Regardless of a country’s size, an import tariff clearly raises both the
import price and the quantity produced; yet the industrial relative size for the import
sector does not necessarily increase since the tariff could indirectly change the sizes of
other sectors as well.
Therefore, whether strong protection in an industry leads to high output share
remains an empirical question. In fact, one can easily f‌ind opposing evidence for dif-
ferent industries. For example, in the 1960s, the USA abandoned high trade protec-
tion on its footwear industry. As a result, the output in the footwear industry
decreased dramatically (Cassing and Hillman, 1986). Conversely, the story of the
garment industry shows another side of the coin. Traditionally, the garment industry
is one of the most highly protected sectors by the US government, yet its output share
relative to the gross domestic product (GDP) shows a decreasing trend over the years.
In this paper we therefore estimate the effect of trade protection for an industry on
its output share. Our paper contributes to the literature from two important perspec-
tives. First, we extend the seminal work of Harrigan (1997) by considering the role of
trade protection in a neoclassical trade specif‌ication model which believes that the
* Yu: China Center for Economic Research, National School of Development, Peking University, Beijing
100871, China. Tel: +86-10-6275-3109; Fax: +86-10-6275-1474; E-mail: mjyu@ccer.pku.edu.cn. Tian: School
of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business and Economics (UIBE),
Beijing 100871, China. The authors thank Robert Feenstra and Xiaopeng Yin for their very full comments
for this project. However, all errors remains those of the authors.
Review of Development Economics, 18(2), 231–253, 2014
DOI:10.1111/rode.12081
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
pattern of international specif‌ication and trade is jointly determined by technology
difference alàthe Ricardian model and factor endowment difference alàthe
Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanik model. In contrast to an ideal free-trade setup, our empirical
specif‌ication is closer to reality by allowing various trade protections such as import
tariffs and non-barrier barriers such as import quota or export subsidy. We f‌ind strong
evidence that trade protection plays a role in determining industrial size for some
manufacturing industries.
Second, our empirical f‌indings themselves also enrich the understanding of the
effect of trade protection. It is a conventional wisdom that an industry could grow
faster under import protection. For more than a century policy makers and even some
economists believe the idea of “infant industry protection” as a favorable argument
for trade protection. Our empirical f‌indings instead cast doubt on such a theoretical
conjecture. After controlling for factor endowments and technology improvement, we
f‌ind empirical evidence that trade protection does not greatly help increase a sector’s
relative size, measured by its industrial output share over GDP.
The objective of this paper is to see how an import tariff imposed on an industry
can change production sizes of itself and other related industries particularly in the
USA. It is important to emphasize that a change in industrial production size could
occur for reasons other than the change of an import tariff. First, the change of indus-
trial output share could be due to factor endowment changes caused by a movement
of international factors or other reasons. For example, consider a standard
Heckscher–Ohlin model, in which labor is migrated from the foreign country to the
home country. The home country’s labor-intensive sector will expand according to the
Rybczynski theorem.
Second, it might be because of the export-biased technology improvement. The
advanced technology used in export-biased industries causes the expansion of export-
able. Accordingly, resources will shift toward the exporting sectors from the import-
ing sectors, which in turn causes the shrink of the importing sectors. As known as
the “Immiserizing growth” initiated by Bhagwati (1958), for a large country, if the
exportable-biased growth reduces the output of the importable good, and if the
foreign demand for such an importable good is inelastic, then its national welfare
would be reduced, in large part, because of the deterioration of its terms of trade.
Third, nontradable sectors grow very fast today. For example, according to the
reports from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), the weight of professional ser-
vices related to the GDP in the USA reached 20% in 2006. Such a quick move would
make tradable sectors shrink relatively, which in turn also leads to a relative decline
of import-competing tradable sectors. In addition, other domestic industrial policies
such as a production subsidy on import-competing commodities could also make sizes
of importing sectors shrink.
Finally, factors from the demand side could affect the industrial output share as
well. For instance, an increase in the price of substitutable commodities for an
industry could push the industrial demand curve shift right, since consumers will
substitute commodities in the industry for their substitutable goods. Accordingly,
both the equilibrium price and output increase, given others constant. In other
words, an increase in the price of substitutables for an industry could affect its
industrial output share.
Therefore, to estimate the effect of trade policy on production size for each indus-
try, we need to control for other factors affecting industrial production size such as
factor endowments, technology and price changes from other industries. We adopt a
functional form of translog GDP system to handle this task for two reasons.
232 Wei Tian and Miaojie Yu
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT