A Mean‐Preserving Increase in Ambiguity and Portfolio Choices

AuthorYi‐Chieh Huang,Larry Y. Tzeng
Date01 December 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12188
Published date01 December 2018
©2017 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol.85, No. 4, 993–1012 (2018).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12188
A Mean-Preserving Increase in Ambiguity and
Portfolio Choices
Yi-Chieh Huang
Larry Y. Tzeng
Abstract
This article investigates under what conditions an increase in ambiguity re-
duces demand for an uncertain asset (or raises demand for coinsurance). We
find that the comparative statics of ambiguity and of risks have structuralsim-
ilarities under the smooth ambiguity aversion model (Klibanoff, Marinacci,
and Mukerji, 2005). The determinant condition on ambiguity preferences
is analogous to that on risk preferences. However, the comparative statics
have fundamental differences under the ˛-maxmin model (Ghirardato, Mac-
cheroni, and Marinacci, 2004). When relative risk aversion is less than 1, only
an increase in ambiguity,which broadens support for an investor ’s belief in
the probability of the return distribution in the manner of a strong increase
in risk, can reduce demand for an uncertain asset.
Introduction
Since Ellsberg (1961) uncovered the phenomenon from the experiment that people
are generally averse to the uncertainty of probabilities, ambiguity and ambiguity
aversion have received much attention in the literature. In particular, the literature
shows the importance of ambiguity and ambiguity aversion in financial markets.1
Yi-ChiehHuang is at the Department of Risk Management and Insurance, Feng Chia University,
Taichung City 40724, Taiwan. Huang can be contacted via e-mail: huangyic@fcu.edu.tw.Larry
Y. Tzeng is at the Department and Graduate Institute of Finance, National Taiwan University,
TaipeiCity 10048, Taiwanand at Risk and Insurance Research Center (RIRC), National Chengchi
University, Taipei City 11605, Taiwan. Tzeng can be contacted via e-mail: tzeng@ntu.edu.tw.
We deeply appreciate the anonymous coeditor’s helpful and valuable suggestions. We also
would like to express our gratefulness to the three anonymous referees for their detailed and
helpful comments and suggestions. Huang and Tzeng acknowledge financial support from the
research grant of Ministry of Science and Technology(MOST) (MOST 104-2410-H-035-052 and
MOST 102-2410-H-002-028-MY3, respectively).
1In addition to financial markets, recently, research on decision making under ambiguity has
also been extended to genetics and medical science. For example, Chew, Ebstein, and Zhong
(2012) provide a better understanding of decision making under ambiguity by identifying the
genes related to ambiguity aversion. Berger,Bleichrodt, and Eeckhoudt (2013) show that under
ambiguity aversion, demand for treatmentincreases when a patient’s health status is uncertain,
but decreaseswhen the effect of treatment is uncertain. Moreover, Hoy,Peter,and Richter (2014)
find that ambiguity aversion can help explain why people are disinclined to receive a costless
993
994 The Journal of Risk and Insurance
Regarding asset pricing, some papers demonstrate that ambiguity-averse investors
react asymmetrically to good and bad news in stock markets (Epstein and Schneider,
2008) and prefer trading stocks according to aggregate information rather than
separable information (Caskey, 2009). Other papers find evidence from survey data
that ambiguity aversion can help to explain several anomalies in stock markets, such
as the higher risk premiums of small firms (Olsen and Troughton, 2000) and the
equity premium puzzle (Rieger and Wang, 2012).
Regarding portfolio choices, the literature shows, theoretically and empirically, that
when considering the uncertainty of expected returnsand ambiguity aversion, the out-
of-sample performance of the optimal portfolio measured by the Sharpe ratio is better
than those of the mean-variance and Bayesian portfolios (Garlappi, Uppal, and Wang,
2007). Several papers find that ambiguity-averse investors’ holdings of risky assets
decrease with greater ambiguity in dynamic settings (e.g., Fei, 2009; Faria and Correia-
da-Silva, 2016) and with greater ambiguity aversion under certain conditions (Gollier,
2011). In a portfolio choice experiment, Ahn et al. (2014) find that about 25 percent
of subjects exhibit ambiguity aversion.2Further, increasing numbers of papers point
out the significant impact of ambiguity and/or ambiguity aversion on equilibrium
in the insurance markets (e.g., Koufopoulos and Kozhan, 2014),3insurance decisions
such as demand for self-insurance and self-protection (e.g., Snow,2011; Alary,Gollier,
and Treich, 2013),4and the pricing of insurance premiums (e.g., Cabantous, 2007;
Cabantous et al., 2011; Huang, Huang, and Tzeng, 2013).5
Although the above-mentioned papers provide insight into the influence of ambi-
guity and ambiguity aversion on portfolio choices and insurance decisions, none has
explored the impact of an increase in ambiguity in terms of a change in the probability
distribution on demand for a risky asset (or demand for coinsurance) when the return
distribution is uncertain. As in Gollier (2011), throughout this article we refer to a
risky asset with an uncertain return distribution as an uncertain asset.6Following this
line of literature, the aim of this article is to find the conditions under which there is a
genetic test, as the genetic test introduces uncertainty regarding the probability of genetic
mutation.
2However,the results also revealed that most subjects (about 65 percent) are ambiguity neutral.
3Koufopoulos and Kozhan (2014) demonstrate that an increase in ambiguity can improve the
welfare of both high- and low-risk individuals when the former face the sufficiently larger
increase in ambiguity than the latter.
4Snow (2011) shows that both the presence of ambiguity and an increasein ambiguity aversion
raise demand for self-insurance and self-protection in two states of nature. When considering
multiple states of nature, Alary,Gollier, and Treich(2013) find the conditions under which am-
biguity aversion increases demand for self-insurance but reduces demand for self-protection.
5Cabantous’s (2007) survey results suggest that uncertainty of loss probability induces actu-
aries to charge a higher premium. From experimental data, Cabantous et al. (2011) confirm
Cabantous’s finding and further found that different types of ambiguity lead to differential
premiums charged by insurers. Regarding insurance bargaining, Huang, Huang, and Tzeng
(2013) show that both more ambiguity and more ambiguity aversion cause the client to settle
with the insurer on a higher premium for a full-coverage contract.
6Gollier (2011) interchangeably uses the terms uncertain asset and ambiguous asset.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT