A Marketer's View of Competition and Antitrust

AuthorAllan D. Shocker
Published date01 March 2007
Date01 March 2007
DOI10.1177/0003603X0705200106
Subject MatterArticle
THE
ANTITRUST
BULLETIN:
Vol.
52, No. IjSpring 2007 :
95
Amarketer's view of
competition
and
antitrust
By
ALLAN
D.
SHOCKER*
I. INTRODUCTION
Marketing
and
antitrust are strongly interrelated. Typically it is cer-
tain objectionable marketing practices
that
have
made
antitrust action
necessary.
And
antitrust
decisions can affect future marketing prac-
tices
and
alternative strategies. Pricing
and
promotion practices, in
particular,
have
figured
prominently
in
many
legal
actions
(e.g.,
deceptive pricing or advertising,
predatory
pricing, refusals to deal,
"unfair"
competition,
and
mergers
and
acquisitions
that
potentially
offer
marketing
efficiencies).
Aftermarket
antitrust
cases, however,
largely involve
product
interrelations;
which
is
not
to
say
that
the
other
aspects of marketing
do
not
matter,
but
it seems beneficial to
focus
on
these. Aftermarkets, for
the
most
part,
sell
products
and
*Allan D. Shocker is retired from the University of
Minnesota-Twin
Cities,
where
he
had
been the Curtis L. Carlson Professor of Marketing in its
Carlson School of Management. After retirement he served as Visiting Profes-
sor
of Marketing at San Francisco State University (COB), Carnegie Mellon
University (Tepper),
and
the University of California at Davis (GSM). Con-
tact: ashocker®sfsu.edu.
AUTHORS
NOTE: I wish to thank
Prof.
Gregory
Gundlach,
Professor
of
Marketing
at
theUniversity ofNorth
Florida,
for
his
helpful
comments
and
suggestions
to
improve
presentation
of this
article.
It
reflects
my
thoughts
and views
regarding
the
intersec-
tionof antitrust with
marketing
in the
context
of
aftermarkets.
©2007by
Federal
LegalPublications, Inc.
96 :
THE
ANTITRUST
BULLETIN:
Vol. 52, No. l/Spring 2007
services
that
complement the
product
being
sold
in the fore- or pri-
mary
market.
The
value
of
owning
the
aftermarket
product
comes
about
because
the
foremarket
product
is
already
owned,
or
being
contemplated,
and
they are
used
together.
The
aftermarket
product
is
often essential to a
buyer's
ability to gain greater value from the fore-
market
product
and
to
serve
other
buyer
requirements.
Antitrust
issues
can
arise
because
continued
use of
the
foremarket
product
sometimes creates
what
is
termed
lock-in or switching costs for
buy-
ers, forcing
them
to continue to
purchase
products
in
the
aftermarket
to benefit from
them
both. Patents
and
other
forms of
market
power
have
been
used
to
keep
buyers
tied
to
particular
sellers'
brands.
Patents
arguably
do
not,
per
se, confer
market
power,'
But,
when
combined
with
appropriate
marketing action to encourage
demand
for both products, they tie the
two
together.
Then
patents can
playa
role if they restrict
the
aftermarket product's usability
with
a
product
from
the
foremarket. A classic example is
the
razor
and
blade relation
(also printers
and
ink) where
only
certain aftermarket
brands
(blades)
are designed to function with specific foremarket
products
(razors).
Marketers also recognize this connection
and
seek
advantage
through
pricing,
product
design, warranty, packaging, distribution,
and
pro-
motion.
But
relations
between
fore-
and
aftermarket
products
are
more involved
than
these examples alone
may
suggest.
These relations are the focus of this article because they affect the
marketing practices
that
sometimes lead to
antitrust
concerns. First, I
examine some of
the
characteristics of real competitive markets
and
the factors
both
marketing
and
antitrust
need
to
understand
in
order
to create desirable courses of action
and
accurately predict
the
out-
The recent
Supreme
Court case, Illinois Tool Works Inc. v. Indep. Ink,
Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1281 (2006), cited several legal precedents to reach this conclu-
sion. The
Supreme
Court
ruled in favor of
the
plaintiff on a
narrow
legal
issue. This case was joined through amicus briefs by
many
other large firms
who
also sought legal protection for their ability to use
patent
protection to
exert market
power
over
the sale of a tied,
nonpatented
product. The
Court
sided
with
Illinois Tool Works, holding that, because a
patent
does not neces-
sarily confer
market
power, aplaintiff
must
prove
that
a
defendant
has
such
power
in the tying
product
before a court will conclude
that
such
an arrange-
ment is illegal. Some of the arguments
advanced
by this article could
help
with
such
proof.
A
MARKETER'S
VIEW
97
comes of actions or legal remedies being contemplated.
The
similarity
of antitrust to marketing concerns is discussed, as are
some
of their
differences. The
nature
of the general ties
that
bind
markets together
in
buyer
behaviors is examined. The role of
buyer
purpose
and
the
conceptualization
of
products
as
bundles
of benefits
and
costs are
used
to explain
the
relationships
and
assess
the
structure of competi-
tive markets. Because
buyer
decisions
often
have
antecedents
and
consequences, fore-
and
aftermarkets
become
somewhat
arbitrary
designations.
I
examine
market
structure
analysis
(MSA), a
set
of
research procedures marketers use to identify competitors from buy-
ers' viewpoints
and
assess the extent of
interproduct/brand
substi-
tutability. I
conclude
by
noting
that
marketing
and
litigation
may
sometimes be substitutes
and
discuss ways by
which
the
court
or liti-
gants can include
some
or all of these ideas
into
future
behaviors.
The economies of
the
twenty-first
century
are significantly more
complex
than
those of earlier years largely
due
to
advanced
technol-
ogy, globalization,
open
trade agreements,
and
other
forces. Recogni-
tion of this is
important
because
many
legal decisions
were
rendered
when
economies
were
simpler
and
thus
may
not
always be
adequate
as
precedents
for
today's
circumstances.
Competition
can
cross
national
boundaries
and
be subject to different regulations, jurisdic-
tions, customs,
and
precedents. Products
and
services can be created
or
disappear
via a few lines of
computer
code. Firms are more likely
today
to
market
and
sell
multiple
products
and
worry
about
their
joint profitability. They
may
partner
with
potential or actual competi-
tors to enter
new
global markets or for technical reasons. Sometimes
the products of a single seller will even
compete
with
each other. Sell-
ers
may
offer
products
in
both
fore-
and
aftermarkets to
have
control
over
the
interfaces
between
them
that
assure
they
operate
well
together. Such control
may
provide acompetitive
advantage
through
product
quality
(e.g.,
Apple's
control of
both
its
iPod
and
content
provider, iTunes,
and
the
smooth
functioning of their interface is an
important
competitive advantage).' The Internet
has
changed
the
way
sellers
market
and
increased the ability of
buyers
to influence
both
sellers
and
other
buyers. Buyers can easily
obtain
product
informa-
See Walter S. Mossberg, Microsoft's
Zune
Challenges iPod,
WALL
ST.
J.,
November 9, 2006, http://ptech.wsj.com/archive/ptech-20061109.html.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT