Market Definition in Differentiated Goods When the Final Consumer Buys the Good: Insights from the H&R Block Case

AuthorMalcolm B. Coate
Published date01 September 2014
Date01 September 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1177/0003603X1405900311
Subject MatterH&R Block: A Merger in a Consumer Good—Article
THE ANTITRUST BUL L E T I N :Vol. 59, N o. 3/Fall 2 014 :619
Market definition in differentiated
goods when the final consumer
buys the good: Insights
from the H&R Block case
BYMALCOLM B. COATE*
This article addresses the development of market definition analysis
in three recent merger cases: Staples,Whole Foods, and H&R Block. The
discussion traces the evolution of the market concept from the naïve
Brown Shoe criteria to the price discrimination analysis implicit in Sta-
ples to the current application of diversion theory in the H&R Block
case. By replacing fact with theory, the diversion approach to market
definition runs the risk of returning to the world of Brown Shoe. Addi-
tional discussion of H&R Block s uggests t hat price d iscrimin ation
remains relevant and could have been developed through further fac-
tual study. Moreover,even if theory is used to define a narrow market,
the analyst must address a range of entry issues befo re concluding
that the merger is likely to substantially lessen competition.
KEY WORDS:m arket de finiti on,diffe rentiat ed goods, H &R Block , price
discrimination,merger policy,antitrust
© 2014by Federal Legal Publications, Inc.
* Economist, Federal Trade Commission.
AUTHOR’S NOTE: The analyses and conclusions set forth in this paper are my own
and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Trade Commission, any indi-
vidual commissioner, or any commission bureau. I would like to thank Jeffrey Fischer
and Kent Bernard for helpful comments on this article.
I. INTRODUCTION
H&R Block is the latest in a series of unilateral-effects merger deci-
sions addressing competition in differentiated product markets in
which the customer is an individual consumer.1Mergers in these mar-
kets are more difficult to evaluate, because (1) product differentiation
complicates the market definition analysis by shifting the focus from
market-wide to localized competitive effects, and (2) the sale of the
product to individual consumers marginalizes one important source
of evidence. Because the standard approach to market definition
offered in the 1982 Horizontal Merger Guidelines expects market-
wide effe cts, merger revie w in many different iated markets m ust
shoehorn a customized unilateral concern into the market definition
algorithm. This may be particularly difficult if anticompetitive effects
are limited to a niche in a broad po tential market. Interviews with
final consumers generally provide no real insight into either market
definition or likely competitive effects due to the obvious limitations
on information available to the individual consumer. Given the rele-
vant case law finds failure to prove a concentrated market means the
dismissal of the merger challenge,2plaintiffs face strong pressure to
define markets by any means necessary.
Although the plaintiff’s angst over market definition is under-
standable, economic analysts can define narrow markets when it is
appropriate. For example, price discrimination concerns may justify a
focus on a competitive niche within a broader market. But the applica-
tion of theoretical structures designed to create narrow markets runs
the risk of establishing a policy in which competition is evaluated only
by reviewing the product offerings of the merger partners and their
immediate competitors. Such a policy could block mergers even when
broader competitive realities preclude supracompetitive pricing.
620 :THE ANT I T R U S T BULLETIN:Vol. 59, No. 3/ Fall 2014
1United States v. H&R Block, Inc., 833 F. Supp. 2d 36 (D.D.C. 2011). For
a discussion of the cas e, see Joseph J. Simons & Ma lcolm B. Coate, U.S. v.
H&R Block : An Illust ration of t he DOJ’s New, but Co ntrovers ial Appro ach to
Market Definition, J. COMPETITION L. & ECON. (forthcoming 2014), available at
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2225395.
2See, e.g., Un ited States v. Englehard C orp. 970 F. Supp. 1463 (M .D.
Ga.), aff’d, 126 F.3d 1302 (11th Cir. 1997), and United States v. Sungards, 172 F.
Supp. 2d 172 (D.D.C. 2001).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT