Making Firms Liable for Consumers’ Mistaken Beliefs: Applications to the U.S. Mortgage and Credit Card Markets

Published date01 December 2018
Date01 December 2018
AuthorAlexei Alexandrov
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jels.12203
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 15, Issue 4, 800–841, December 2018
Making Firms Liable for Consumers’
Mistaken Beliefs: Applications to the
U.S. Mortgage and Credit Card Markets
Alexei Alexandrov *
In theory, an introduction of a liability on firms, related to the difference between con-
sumers’ beliefs and the effective terms of purchase/contract, can improve both social
welfare and consumer surplus, depending on the relative magnitudes of: (1) decrease
in the gap between the beliefs and the effective terms of the contract due to the intro-
duction of the liability, (2) output decrease or price increase, and (3) efficiency of
administering the liability (and the amount transferred). I do not find statistically sig-
nificant evidence of (2) in two examples of instituting a similar liability: when several
large U.S. credit card issuers dropped mandatory arbitration clauses (that effectively
precluded class action lawsuits) and when U.S. residential mortgage creditors became
liable for failing to consider a borrower’s future ability to repay the mortgage, suggest-
ing that these events improved consumer surplus and might have improved social
welfare.
I. INTRODUCTION
In many markets consumers hold mistaken beliefs. Although in some markets consumers
are correct in their beliefs on average, this is not always the case. Sometimes, mechanisms
such as reputation, competition, or mandated disclosure, all discussed later, might
*1221 First Ave, Apt. 503, Seattle WA 98101; email: alexei01@gmail.com. The views expressed are those of the
author and do not necessarily represent those of his current or past employers. The author is grateful to Ron Bor-
zekowski, Kelvin Chen, and Will Wade-Gery for conversations about these topics. Portions of the article would
either not have been possible or would have taken years longer if not for the work done by Brian Bucks, Albert
Chang, Arland Kane, and Stefano Sciolli on projects using the same data. The author also thanks the participants
of CFPB’s Office of Research Brown Bag, of the International Industrial Organization Conference (especially dis-
cussant Wilko Bolt), of the Conference on Empirical Legal Studies (especially discussant Florencia Marotta -Wurg-
ler), and Oren Bar-Gill, Chris Drahozal, Andrew Rhodes, and Jean Sternlight for their detailed comments on an
earlier draft. He is also grateful to the editor and to an anonymous referee. Any remaining errors in the draft are
solely the author’s.
800
nonetheless result in a well-functioning market. However, in many cases, consumers’ mis-
taken beliefs lead to a market failure.
1
In many such markets firms can either alter the effective terms of contract to
better correspond to consumer beliefs or alter consumer beliefs to better corre-
spondtotheeffectivetermsofthecontract.First, using a theoretical model to place
the following empirical tests in the right context, I show that such an intervention,
under certain conditions, increases both social welfare and consumer surplus in
such markets, even in the ones where other mechanisms might not have succeeded.
Empirically, I do not find statistically significant price increase (in the U.S. credit
card market) or statistically significant quantity decrease (in the U.S. mortgage mar-
ket) due to such interventions (with all standard caveats). To test for the magnitude
or presence of positive effects, one would need data on deterrence that are unavail-
able, at least for these particular interventions.
In the theoretical model, introducing this liability results in (1) firms shrinking
the gap between the effective terms of the contract and consumers’ beliefs by shifting
at least one of these two variables.
2
However, this (2) increases firms’ cost and there-
fore lowers quantity produced, to the extent of the marginal cost increase adjusted by
the cost pass-through rate. Also, there are (3) the liability transfer itself and the
administrative costs of effecting this liability transfer, for example, court costs and law-
yer fees.
3
The overall impact on both social welfare and consumer surplus depends on
the interplay between these three effects.
Throughout the article I focus on two real-world examples of this type of a legal
liability: one connected to the U.S. credit card issuers’ exposure to class action law-
suits that started in late 2009 due to the issuers agreeing to drop their mandatory arbi-
tration clauses, and the other connected to the ability to repay (ATR) regulation in
1
DellaVigna and Malmendier (2004), Heidhues and Ko
¨szegi (2010), and Grubb (2015) all show that in particular
settings with particular behavioral biases, perfect competition does not maximize social welfare, and thus an inter-
vention might increase social welfare. Alexandrov (2017) shows that this is the case for virtually any behavioral bias,
and I adopt the model in that paper to allow for legal action. The model can also be viewed as addressing the lack
of salience of form terms (and other attributes). Policy interventions, like the ones that I analyze, arguably move
us toward the “reasonable expectations” doctrine discussed by Korobkin (2003). Such interventions are another
way to influence sellers’ ex-ante incentives, instead of (or, possibly, together with) Korobkin’s (2003) suggestion
that the courts should consider leaving sellers with the worst ex-post default options to ensure that sellers have the
correct ex-ante incentives. Note that, under some assumptions, the market can ameliorate or fix behavioral biases
completely; see, for example, Schwartz (2008). See also Schwartz (2015) for a discussion on regulation when con-
sumers might have behavioral biases.
2
This is, effectively, deterrence; see, for example, Becker (1968) and Kaplow and Shavell (2001).
3
As discussed further, effect (3) has different implications for consumer surplus and for social welfare. From the
point of view of social welfare, effect (3) in and of itself is weakly negative: this is a transfer, and at best it is per-
fectly efficient, but sometimes there will be administrative costs. From the point of view of consumer surplus, effect
(3) in and of itself is weakly positive: even if there are significant administrative costs, consumers still receive at
least a little of that monetary transfer.
Making Firms Liable for Consumers’ Mistaken Beliefs 801
the U.S. mortgage market that became effective in early 2014.
4
The available data only
allow me to attempt to estimate causally the magnitude of effect (2), increased prices
or decreased quality in these two markets.
5
The estimates are not statistically signifi-
cant: I cannot rule out that the introduction of such liability had no adverse impact
on prices or quantity. However, in the credit card application, the magnitude of the
standard errors is, arguably, economically significant, and thus I cannot rule out an
economically significant response.
For each of the two empirical analyses, I use administrative account/mortgage-level
datasets, accounting for close to 90 percent of each of the markets. For identification, I
use a difference-in-differences setup in the credit card market (four of the issuers have
dropped mandatory arbitration clauses, while others have not) and regression discontinu-
ity in the mortgage market (lenders making fewer than 500 loans were effectively
exempted from the regulation).
In the credit card application, finding not statistically significant effects, but not
being able to rule out economically significant responses, is disappointing from the statis-
tical power perspective. However, it serves as a warning to future researchers regarding
the difficulty of isolating effects (or noneffects) of contractual changes on prices, even
with excellent data. In particular, close to 50 percent of the U.S. credit card market
(by volume) dropped arbitration clauses, and I used a detailed account-level monthly
administrative dataset covering over 90 percent of U.S. accounts, and this was still not
enough to categorically rule out economically significant effects (or to rule out no
effects). One setting change that could help is having many more treated firms than four
(albeit very large) firms that I analyze.
Much of the behavioral literature’s suggestions for addressing the market failure
imposed by behavioral biases is ways of making consumers behave as if they are closer to ratio-
nal: nudges, choice architecture, or taxes on products like cigarettes, fatty foods, and sugary
beverages.
6
Another way of fixing the internality imposed by consumers’ behavioral biases is
making firms internalize consumers’ internality.
7
The liability that I analyze is an example of
alleviating the market failure by making the firms accountable for consumers’ biases. The idea
is connected to some of the more recent literature on disclosures. There is evidence that
4
See the following sections and New York Times (2015) for the first article in a three-piece long-form series on
mandatory arbitration clauses. Also see, for example, New York Times (2016) on the U.S. Consumer Financial Pro-
tection Bureau’s notice of proposed rulemaking that would not allowing mandatory arbitration clauses to be used
to block class action lawsuits in the consumer finance space in the United States. The ability to repay rule was the
key part of a package of rules that the U.S. Congress instructed the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau to pass
as a part of the Dodd-Frank Act, with the intention of preventing future mortgage crises; see New York Times
(2013) and Slate (2013) for examples of popular press coverage when the rule was finalized. After the rule was
finalized, Congress exercised its power under the Congressional Review Act and repealed the rule.
5
The causal claim is subject to interpreting the Ross case as exogenous variation, discussed in further detail below.
6
See, for example, Jolls et al. (1998), Camerer et al. (2003), Sunstein and Thaler (2003), Jolls and Sunstein
(2006), Johnson et al. (2012), Allcott et al. (2014), and Madrian (2014).
7
See, for example, Chetty (2015), discussing literature on externalities.
802 Alexandrov

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT