Local Content Requirements Versus Tariff Equivalents: How We Measure Matters

Published date01 May 2017
Date01 May 2017
AuthorDorothee Flaig,Susan F. Stone
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12426
Local Content Requirements Versus Tariff
Equivalents: How We Measure Matters
Dorothee Flaig and Susan F. Stone
OECD, Trade and Agriculture Directorate, Paris, France
1. INTRODUCTION
IN the wake of the economic crisis in 2008, governments came under intense pressure to
provide quick solutions to large employment problems. At the same time, many govern-
ments felt at a loss to effectively stimulate domestic activities given the large influence global
value chains (GVCs) and international fragmentation were seen to have on domestic produc-
tion. However, as the crisis itself so starkly illustrated, the inter-reliance of economies has
never been greater and the traditional go-to remedy of previous downturns, that is tariff
increases, suddenly became a self-defeating policy.
The implementation of tariffs or quotas was further inhibited by the monitoring process
that was put in place under the auspices of the G20. The G20 came to prominence in the
wake of the crisis and was quick to condemn any use of trade distorting tariff measures: We
underscore the critical importance of rejecting protectionism and not turning inward in times
of financial uncertainty. In this regard, within the next 12 months, we will refrain from rais
ing new barriers to investment or to trade in goods and services, imposing new export restric-
tions, or implementing World Trade Organization (WTO) inconsistent measures to stimulate
exports(G20 Statement released 15 November 2008). This pledge has been repeated at the
majority of subsequent G20 meeting.
However, as time passed and recoveries faltered, governments increasingly sought other
ways to promote domestic economies. In a time of budgetary austerity, various types of local-
isation requirements began to be seen as a way to boost domestic industry without incurring
significant fiscal outlay. By mandating local sourcing of goods and services, the real cost of
these policies is born by a large group of purchasers and competing international suppl iers
and thus are difficult to measure or track. However, precisely because these measures are opa-
que, the accurate identification and measurement of their costs is an important trade policy
concern.
The purpose of this paper was to outline a new approach to the measurement of localisa-
tion barriers to trade, specifically in the form of local content requirements (LCRs). This
paper proceeds by first discussing the rise in the use of LCRs as a trade policy tool. It then
develops a quantitative approach to modelling these policies in a CGE framework. This paper
argues that implementing these measures in their quantitative form, as opposed to converting
them to tariff equivalents, has important implications for measured outcomes. The price mech-
anism implied by the tariff equivalents fails to capture the more subtle spillover effects
The CGE model employed in this study was developed by and for OECD: Stone et al. (2015) and
OECD (2015), METRO version 1 model documentation, Trade and Agriculture Directorate, OECD, Jan-
uary. The authors are grateful to Frank van Tongeren for comments on this work as well as to partici-
pants of the 17th annual GTAP conference and various OECD seminars where this work has been
presented. This work should not be reported as representing the official views of the OECD or of its
member countries. The opinions expressed and arguments employed are those of the authors.
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 931
The World Economy (2017)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12426
The World Economy
observed in the market place. Leaving the LCRs in their quantitative form allows these costs
to be better captured by the analysis.
2. LOCAL CONTENT REQUIREMENTS
The incidence of non-tariff measures (NTMs), while applied in varying forms for years,
has been growing since the crisis. In fact, there is evidence that the rise in globalisation,
through GVCs and other cross-border interactions, has contributed to both the rise in the use
of NTMs as well as to their cost (Osgood, 2012). In this world of GVCs, the cost of protec-
tion can be higher than generally thought (Miroudot et al., 2013). As intermediate inputs are
traded across borders multiple times, downstream firms end up paying higher costs for
imported inputs in addition to the barriers they face on their own exports. The effective bur-
den for the exporter can thus be several orders of magnitude over what nominal tariffs or
NTMs show. Consequently, firms are campaigning vigorously for the monitoring and elimina-
tion of a variety of NTMs.
1
Among the fastest growing NTMs are LCRs. Historically, LCRs were attached to foreign
direct investment (FDI) as a means of generating domestic jobs. By mandating a certain per-
centage of inputs to be purchased domestically, or a certain percentage of people employed
locally, domestic governments were looking to guarantee the realisation of the anticipated
spillovers from these projects.
2
However, the motivation for many of the LCRs put in place
since the 2008 crisis has gone beyond job creation. Today, LCRs are being used as a way to
develop expertise in emerging high technology and renewable energy sectors, for example.
Related to this is the desire to obtain a portion of the vast and lucrative business associated
with large multinationals and GVC trade (Hufbauer et al., 2013).
Local content requirements are similar to import quotas in that they use quantities rather
than prices to influence the geographic distribution of business. The political appeal of LCRs
is strong as they represent no explicit financial outlays. As opposed to price preferences for
domestic firms, tariffs and subsidies, the cost imposed on purchasers (whether they be house-
holds or firms) is opaque and often totally hidden with LCRs. The WTO and many RTA
agreements remain unclear with respect to quantity restrictions. For example, quantity restric-
tions only violate provisions under the Government Procurement Agreement (GPA) of the
WTO for a set of specific activities agreed to in the GPA. LCRs tied to services seldom con-
flict with obligations under GATS because, for the most part, those commitments are limited
to pre-existing market access.
Various sources estimate that between 90 and 200, new LCR measures have been put in
place since 2008.
3
According to Hufbauer et al. (2013), countries have considered or imple-
mented almost 120 new LCRs. They define these LCRs as follows:
Classic mandatory LCRs set as percentages of goods or services;
Tax, tariff or price concessions conditioned on local procurement;
1
For recent discussions of this topic see: http://www.oecd.org/fr/tad/echdev/international-business-dialo-
gue-2013.htm and http://www.digitaleurope.org/DocumentDownload.aspx?Command=Core_Download&
EntryId=615.
2
LCRs had the added benefit of generating greater support in the domestic market for many invest-
ment projects. See for example, G
org and Greenaway (2004) for a review.
3
See for example, the WTO G20 Monitoring Reports, Global Trade Alert and European Commission’s
Market Access Database.
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
932 D. FLAIG AND S. F. STONE

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT