Licensing versus assignment: Innovation transfer in an asymmetric duopoly

Published date01 December 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jpet.12414
AuthorShuai Niu
Date01 December 2019
J Public Econ Theory. 2019;21:12861308.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jpet1286
|
© 2019 Wiley Periodicals, Inc.
Received: 11 July 2019
|
Accepted: 3 November 2019
DOI: 10.1111/jpet.12414
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Licensing versus assignment: Innovation
transfer in an asymmetric duopoly
Shuai Niu
School of Economics, Shandong
University, Jinan, China
Correspondence
Shuai Niu, School of Economics,
Shandong University, No. 27
Shandananlu, Jinan, 250100 Shandong
Province, China.
Email: niushuai1@163.com
Abstract
Suppose that the relatively inefficient firm in an asym-
metric duopoly market develops a nondrastic process
innovation. To maximize returns on the innovation, the
innovator must determine the most lucrative commercial
policy. Should it be inhouse exploitation, or licensing or
assignment? It turns out that the innovator never uses
innovation exclusively. The choice of licensing or assign-
ment depends on the size of the initial cost difference.
When the initial cost difference is relatively small, the
innovator would resort to licensing, whereas when there is
a significant initial cost gap, the innovator would rather
assign the property rights of the innovation to the rival. In
the case of assignment, the assignee may license the
innovation back to the assignor. With the option of reverse
licensing, an assignment will always be more profitable
than (direct) licensing. Interestingly, if the initial cost gap
were sufficiently large, the innovator would exit the
market postassignment, and thus act as an outside
nonoperating licensor.
KEYWORDS
assignment, inhouse exploitation, licensing
JEL CLASSIFICATION
L13; L24; L41
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Suppose that one day an innovative firm creates a process innovation. The innovator wishes to
maximize returns on the innovation. What is the most lucrative commercial policyinhouse
exploitation or licensing or assignment? In the past, most technologyoriented firms focused
exclusively on applying innovation to their own products or services (Lichtenthaler, 2008).
Today, however, an increasing number of innovative firms have started to commercialize their
knowledge assets through external transactions such as licensing or assignment (Jeong, Lee, &
Kim, 2013).
1
What the licensing policy and the assignment policy have in common is that they give
entities other than the innovator access to the innovation. The difference between them lies in
whether or not ownership of the innovation is transferred. Under licensing, the innovator
grants permission for the use of the innovation to another entity, but retains the right to use the
innovation or further license it to other entities. Under the assignment, however, ownership of
the innovation is transferred from the innovator to another entity. Following assignment, the
innovator loses all control of the innovation and can no longer use it, or license others to use it
(Irish, 2005, p. 143).
To put into context comparisons of different commercial policies, think of a homogenous
product market with two producers, Firm 1 and firm 2. Firm 1 produces at a constant marginal
cost of c
1
, and firm 2 produces at marginal cost
c
2
. There are no fixed costs in production and the
two firms engage in quantity competition. Initially, firm 1 is less efficient than firm 2 (i.e.,
cc>
1
2
). The initial cost difference is nondrastic, in the sense that firms are both active in
Cournot equilibrium. One day, firm 1 creates a process innovation. Using this innovation, the
marginal production cost of firm 1 drops to c
x
1, where
x
is the amount of cost reduction.
Depending on the size of xc
x
,
1can be greater than, equal to, or less than
c
2
.If
cxc<
1
2
,
we make necessary restrictions on
x
so that firm 2 will not go out of business in equilibrium if
firm 1 were to apply the innovation exclusively. Suppose that the innovation is a common
one. If firm 2 is given access to the innovation through licensing or assignment, its marginal
cost would decline also by x.
2
The choice of commercial policy affects the cost structure of the duopoly market. Under in
house exploitation, the marginal production cost of firm 1 drops to c
x
1, while that of firm 2
remains at
c
2
. In the case of assignment, firm 1, in losing the right to use the innovation, needs
to produce at the initiallevel marginal cost, c
1
, whereas firm 2, as the new owner of the
innovation, produces at
c
x
2
.
3
Under licensing, firm 1 retains the right to use the innovation,
and produces at c
x
1. Although firm 2 is given permission to apply the innovation in
production, it may need to pay perunit royalties to firm 1.
4
Thus, the marginal aggregate cost of
firm 2 under licensing should be written as
cx
+
2, where
rx[0, ]
is the perunit royalty
rate.
5
Variations in marginal costs affect the equilibrium industry profit under quantity
competition. Suppose that the innovator switches from the policy of inhouse exploitation to
the assignment policy. Then, the sum of the marginal costs remains cc
x
+
12 , but the
1
Statistically, in 2010, about 4% of the Danish patentactive businesses sold their patents, and more than 10% of them outlicensed their patents (refer to http://
www.iptradeportal.com/statisticsontradingipr/tradingpatents.aspx for details). In addition, data from the United States Patent and Trademark Office
indicate that about 13.5% of all granted patents are traded at least once over their life cycle (Serrano, 2010).
2
Refer to Sinha (2016) for an explanation of the difference between a common innovationand a new technology innovation.
3
Note that, due to the initial cost gap, although it is assumed that the exclusive use of the innovation by firm 1 will not drive firm 2 out of the market, it is
entirely possible that the solo application of the innovation by firm 2 may force firm 1 to shut down in equilibrium. We do cover this possibility in this study.
Nonetheless, for brevity, in the introduction, we assume that both firms are active postassignment.
4
Under licensing, the innovator usually requests from the licensee a lumpsum payment and/or some running royalties. Under the assignment, the innovator
can also receive royalties, but lumpsum payments are much more common. Refer to the report titled Should I License or Should I Assign My Patent?by Mary
Bellis at https://www.thoughtco.com/shouldilicenseorshouldiassignmypatent1991823.
5
It is natural to require that r
0
. The other requirement,
r
x
, originates from Shapiro (1985) and is widely adopted in the licensing literature.
NIU
|
1287

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT