Legislative Fragmentation and Government Spending in Presidential Democracies: Bringing Ideological Polarization into the Picture

AuthorOskar Nupia,Marcela Eslava
Date01 August 2017
Published date01 August 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/lsq.12152
MARCELA ESLAVA
OSKAR NUPIA
Universidad de los Andes
Legislative Fragmentation and
Government Spending in
Presidential Democracies:
Bringing Ideological Polarization
into the Picture
We claim that, in presidential democracies, the effect of increasing fragmentation
on government spending should be conditional on polarization, defined as the ideological
distance between the government’s party and other parties in Congress. We buil da mod-
el where this result follows from negotiations between the legislature and an independent
government seeking the approval of its initiatives—as in presidential democracies. Using
cross-country data over time, we test the empirical validity of our claim finding that, in
presidential democracies, there is indeed a positive effect of fragmentation only when
polarization is sufficiently high. The same is not true for parliamentary democracies.
I need to engage in give-and-take, build consensus,and engage in negotiations without
sacrificing principles.
(Indonesian President Susilo Bambang Yudhoyono,
interview airedon CNN, June 15, 2011)
Considerable attention has been given in the literature to the idea
that fragmentation affects f‌iscal discipline (e.g., Bawn and Rosenbluth
2006; De Haan, Sturm, and Beekhuis 1999; Edin and Ohlson 1991;
Elgie and McMenamin 2008; Perotti and Kontopoulos 2002; Pettersson-
Lidbom 2012; Schaltegger and Feld 2009; Volkerink and de Haan 2001;
Weingast, Shepsle, and Johnsen 1981). Fragmentation in this context
refers generically to the number of different interests whose demands are
ref‌lected in the government’s budget. Greater fragmentation is expected
to relax f‌iscal discipline through a standard “common pool of resources”
problem. The greater the number of groups benef‌iting from government
expenditure and sharing its costs, the lesser the degree to which any
LEGISLATIVE STUDIES QUARTERLY, 42, 3, August 2017 387
DOI: 10.1111/lsq.12152
V
C2016 Washington University in St. Louis
particular group internalizes the costs of the goods its members receive
from the government. As a result, the total amount of spending
demanded by participating groups grows with their number. This idea
was put forward a long time ago (e.g., Weingast, Shepsle, and Johnsen
1981) and has since been the subject of a large literature.
A good part of that literature has focused on testing empirically
whether a specif‌ic source of fragmentation, “legislative
fragmentation”—the number of legislating parties in a governing coali-
tion—leads to larger public spending or greater def‌icits.
1
This is also the
focus of our article. The f‌irst wave of studies on this issue concentrated
on samples of countries that have been part of the OECD since its incep-
tion, f‌inding a positive effect of fragmentation on government spending
(e.g., Bawn and Rosenbluth 2006; Perotti and Kontopoulos 2002;
Volkerink and de Haan 2001) or f‌iscal def‌icits (Perotti and Kontopoulos
2002; Volkerink and De Haan 2001). While the results mentioned above
are consistent with the basic thesis that greater fragmentation implies
less f‌iscal discipline, a second wave of studies covering both OECD and
non-OECD countries has found a weaker effect of legislative fragmenta-
tion on f‌iscal balances than that found for the OECD alone (Elgie and
McMenamin 2008; Mukherjee 2003; Woo 2003).
We suggest here that the reason why the link between fragmenta-
tion and f‌iscal discipline appears weaker in non-OECD samples of
countries than in OECD ones may have to do with the predominant pres-
ence of presidential democracies in the former samples and of
parliamentary ones in the latter. As Hankla argued recently, “although
this is rarely acknowledged in the literature, the theoretical link between
party fragmentation and def‌icit spending implicitly assumes a parliamen-
tary system. In presidential systems, the executive is not drawn from the
legislature, and so fragmented assemblies do not translate automatically
into fragmented governments. As a result, there are very good reasons to
believe that the linear relationship between divided legislatures and bud-
get def‌icits may not hold for presidential democracies” (2013, 200). In
particular, the process of ongoing negotiation that characterizes the rela-
tionship between the government and the legislature in a presidential
democracy is absent from the aforementioned theoretical argument. Fac-
tors inf‌luencing that negotiation process may in the end intermediate the
relationship between fragmentation and the budget in presidential
democracies. In this article, we highlight one such factor: the degree of
ideological dispersion between parties that the government negotiates
with, termed here “polarization.”
Once this dimension is considered, the fragmentation-spending
link in presidential democracies should be signif‌icant only in the
388 Marcela Eslava and Oskar Nupia
presence of high enough polarization. The reason is straightforward: In a
context where pork barrel is used by an independent government to
obtain support for its public policies in the legislature (as is the case pre-
dominantly in presidential systems), low polarization around these
policy initiatives implies that the government can obtain legislative sup-
port paying little attention to the coalition parties’ demands for pork. The
common-pool problem imposed by these demands is thus minimized.
However, if there is high polarization around these policy initiatives, the
government party must satisfy at least some of these demands in order to
get legislative approval. In this case, the degree of political fragmentation
should positively affect the level of public spending.
To test our hypothesis that fragmentation matters only in the
presence of high enough polarization, we use information for a panel of
presidential democracies for the period 1978–2005. We measure frag-
mentation based on the number of legislating parties in the governing
coalition and polarization based on the ideological distance between
them (the details are discussed below). We focus on the effects fragmen-
tation and polarization have on central government spending, as
opposed to def‌icits. As noted by Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002), the
theoretical arguments outlined above link fragmentation with govern-
ment spending; arguments translating the pressure derived from
fragmentation into greater def‌icits are less general. It is worth highlight-
ing that fragmentation and polarization, though likely correlated, are
different concepts, as def‌ined above.
Our f‌indings support our hypothesis. We f‌ind that the effect of
fragmentation on government spending in presidential regimes is
increasing in polarization and is signif‌icantly different from zero
(either in a statistical or economic sense) only when there is a high
enough degree of polarization. By contrast, when extending the exer-
cise to a panel of parliamentary democracies, we f‌ind that
fragmentation has an unconditional (i.e., not intermediated by polari-
zation) positive and signif‌icant effect on spending for these countries.
Moreover, our argument and evidence are consistent with previous
f‌indings showing that the direct effect of fragmentation on govern-
ment spending holds for parliamentary democracies but not so in
samples of presidential ones (Mukherjee 2003).
Other recent analyses have studied how institutional and political
differences across types of democracy affect the relationship between
fragmentation and f‌iscal policy (Cheibub 2006; Hallerberg and Marier
2004; Hankla 2013; Wehner 2010). Cheibub (2006) shows that budget
discipline varies between presidential and parliamentary democracies
and that within presidential democracies stronger presidents keep more
389Bringing Ideological Polarization into the Picture

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT