Legislative Abolition of the Death Penalty: A Qualitative Analysis

Date10 February 2012
DOIhttps://doi.org/10.1108/S1059-4337(2012)0000057005
Published date10 February 2012
Pages31-70
AuthorKevin H. Wozniak
LEGISLATIVE ABOLITION OF THE
DEATH PENALTY: A QUALITATIVE
ANALYSIS
Kevin H. Wozniak
ABSTRACT
Legislative action was historically the means by which U.S. states
abolished capital punishment, but such action ceased for decades
following the Supreme Court’s 1976 Gregg decision that reaffirmed the
constitutionality of the death penalty. Despite the fact that several
legislatures have considered abolition bills in the modern era, only three
states successfully enacted such legislation. It is my purpose in this study
to analyze why states are currently struggling to pass abolition legislation
and to determine which factors contribute to success. I conduct a
comparative, qualitative case study of New Jersey, the first state to
legislatively abolish since 1976, and Maryland, a similar state whose
abolition effort recently failed. I analyze the content of legislators’
debates about the abolition bills in committee and on the legislature floor,
as well as news coverage of the abolition efforts in each state’s largest
newspapers. I reach two primary conclusions. First, an abolition bill is
more likely to be passed by Democrats than Republicans, but unified
Democratic control of the government is not a sufficient condition for
abolition. Second, arguments about the risk of wrongful executions and
the deleterious collateral consequences of the death penalty process on the
Studies in Law, Politics, and Society, Volume 57, 31–70
Copyright r2012 by Emerald Group Publishing Limited
All rights of reproduction in any form reserved
ISSN: 1059-4337/doi:10.1108/S1059-4337(2012)0000057005
31
family members of murder victims are powerful sources of political
support for abolition, especially where doubts about the deterrent effect of
the death penalty are widespread. This study reaffirms the central
importance of the innocence frame in the modern death penalty debate,
and it presents the first scholarly analysis of the collateral consequences
frame. These findings may help activists in the abolition movement more
effectively frame their arguments to appeal to legislators.
INTRODUCTION
The death penalty in the USA is a constant source of controversy. Efforts to
abolish capital punishment go back over 100 years and continue to the
present day (Davis, 1957;Galliher, Ray, & Cook, 1992;Haines, 1996;Sarat,
2002). Progress in the modern abolition movement seems to be coming full-
circle. Galliher, Koch, Keys, and Guess (2002) demonstrate that legislative
action was the most common means by which states eliminated capital
punishment from colonial times through the middle of the twentieth
century. However, the Supreme Court’s Furman and Gregg decisions in the
1970s disrupted the spread of abolition legislation throughout the states.
After the Court reaffirmed the constitutionality of capital punishment in
Gregg, most states crafted legislation to strengthen their death penalty
statutes, and abolition efforts shifted toward the courts.
At the turn of the twenty-first century, abolitionists appear to be fighting
their battles within the legislatures once again. Over the past 10 years,
abolition bills were introduced into the legislatures of 14 states (Death Penalty
Information Center, 2011).
1
As of December 2011, only New Jersey, New
Mexico, and Illinois successfully abolished, the first states to do so in the post-
Gregg era. The enactment of these three abolition bills into law, and the fact
that more and more states are debating abolition bills, suggest that the
abolition movement may be picking up where it left off prior to Furman –a
slow but steady progression of legislative abolition (Galliher et al., 2002).
Despite the history and recent surge of abolition legislation across the
states, scholars largely focus on more macrolevel influences on use of the
death penalty (e.g.,Baumgartner, De Boef, & Boydstun, 2008;Fisher& Pratt,
2006;Jacobs & Carmichael, 2004;Jacobs & Kent, 2007;Langbein, 1999;
Nice, 1992;Norrander, 2000;Ruddell & Urbina, 2004); few scholars study
legislative consideration of death penalty bills (Culver, 1999;Galliher &
Galliher, 1997;Galliher et al., 2002, 1992;Koch & Galliher, 1993;Sarat,
KEVIN H. WOZNIAK32
2002).
2
Though the legislature is a common battleground upon which the fate
of the death penalty is decided, we know little about the factors thatinfluence
successful passage or failure of abolition legislation, particularly in the
modern, post-Gregg era. In order to address this gap in our knowledge, I
conduct a qualitative case study of the New Jersey and Maryland legislatures
as they considered abolition legislation. The results from this study will
provide guidance for legislators and activists as legislatures across the USA
continue to debate whether to retain or abolish capital punishment.
THEORETICAL EXPECTATIONS
Party Politics vs. Personal Values
Political scientists debate whether legislative outcomes are driven primarily
by the influence of political parties or by the individual preferences of the
legislators themselves. The debate is centered around the spatial theory of
Krehbiel (1998) on the one hand and the conditional party government
theory of Aldrich and Rohde (1997, 2000) and the cartel theory of Cox and
McCubbins (2005) on the other (see Smith, 2007). Krehbiel argues that
most legislative outcomes can be explained without referring to political
parties; that is, if you know the policy preferences of the legislators, you can
predict the outcome of votes without knowing the legislators’ partisan
affiliations. In other words, Krehbiel implies that parties cannot lead
legislators to cast a vote that is contrary to their personal preferences,
which ultimately leaves parties as a secondary determinant of legislative
votes.
On the other hand, Aldrich and Rohde (1997, 2000) and Cox and
McCubbins (2005) argue that party members cede control over the
legislative agenda to their party leaders in order to ensure that the party’s
favored legislation passes. These theorists argue that party members are
more willing to cede power to their leaders when the preferences of the party
members are homogeneous, meaning that it is unlikely that party leaders
will support legislation that is distasteful to party members. However,
Sinclair (2007) finds evidence that party leaders do attempt to shape the
preferences of individual legislators through both enticement and coercion,
which means that Aldrich, Rohde, Cox, and McCubbins may underestimate
the power of parties to affect legislative outcomes above and beyond the
preferences of the legislators themselves.
Legislative Abolition of the Death Penalty: A Qualitative Analysis 33

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT