Lawyers as Agents of the Devil in a Prisoner's Dilemma Game

Date01 September 2013
Published date01 September 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jels.12014
AuthorGordon B. Dahl,David E. Bloom,Orley Ashenfelter
Lawyers as Agents of the Devil in a
Prisoner’s Dilemma Game
Orley Ashenfelter, David E. Bloom, and Gordon B. Dahl*
Do the parties in a typical dispute face incentives similar to those in the classic prisoner’s
dilemma game? In this article, we explore whether the costs and benefits of legal represen-
tation are such that each party seeks legal representation in the hope of exploiting the other
party, while knowing full well that failing to do so will open up the possibility of being
exploited. The article first shows how it is possible to test for the presence of such an
incentive structure in a typical dispute resolution system. It then reports estimates of the
incentives for the parties to obtain legal representation in wage disputes that were settled by
final-offer arbitration in New Jersey. The article also reports briefly on similar studies of data
from discharge grievances, court-annexed disputes in Pittsburgh, and child custody disputes
in California. In each case, the data provide evidence that the parties face strong individual
incentives to obtain legal representation that make the parties jointly worse off. Using our
New Jersey data, we find that expert agents may well have played a productive role in
moderating the biases of their clients, but only early on in the history of the system. Over
time, the parties slowly evolved to a noncooperative equilibrium where the use of lawyers
becomes nearly universal, despite the fact that agreeing not to hire lawyers is cheaper and
does not appear to alter arbitration outcomes.
The nickname Prisoner’s Dilemma, attributed to A.W. Tucker, derives from the original anecdote used to
illustrate the game. Two prisoners, held incommunicado, are charged with the same crime. They can be
convicted only if either confesses. Further, if only one confesses, he is set free for having turned state’s evidence
and is given a reward to boot. The prisoner who has held out is convicted on the strength of the other’s testimony
and is given a more severe sentence than if he had also confessed. It is in the interest of each to confess whatever
the other does. But it is in their collective interest to hold out.
Rapoport and Chammah (1965)
I. Introduction
This article explores the possibility that the parties to a typical dispute face incentives very
similar to those faced by the prisoners in the classic dilemma described above. The goal is
to explore the possibility that the costs and benefits of legal representation are structured
*Address correspondence to Gordon B. Dahl, Professor of Economics, University of California, San Diego, 9500
Gilman Dr. #0508, La Jolla, CA 92093; email: gdahl@ucsd.edu. Ashenfelter is Joseph Douglas Green 1895 Professor
of Economics, Princeton University; Bloom is Clarence James Gamble Professor of Economics and Demography,
Harvard University.
The authors are grateful to the Russell Sage and Alfred P. Sloan Foundations for financial support. An early
version of this article, with limited data on arbitration cases in New Jersey, appeared as a 1993 NBER working paper.
bs_bs_banner
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 10, Issue 3, 399–423, September 2013
399
so that each individual party seeks representation in the hope of exploiting the other party,
while knowing full well that failing to do so will open up the possibility of being exploited.
In the prisoner’s dilemma, the players are faced with incentives that may lead to
behavior that is not in the best interests of either party. The incentive structures embedded
in such institutions provide a payoff to each party for engaging in noncooperative behavior.
The mere existence of such incentives is not enough to produce the prisoner’s dilemma,
however. To produce inefficiency, the payoffs to noncooperative behavior must be larger
than the costs. Determining whether a particular institution embodies the incentives asso-
ciated with the prisoner’s dilemma thus requires determining whether the individual
benefits from engaging in noncooperative behavior are likely to exceed the costs.
The first part of this article shows how it is possible to test for the presence of an
incentive structure like the one in a prisoner’s dilemma game in a typical dispute resolution
system. The goal is to measure the payoff matrix faced by the parties. Although the analysis
is framed in the context of an arbitration system, it could equally as well be applied to any
dispute resolution system, including the court system. The second part of the article reports
estimates of the incentives for the parties to obtain legal representation in wage disputes
that were settled by final-offer arbitration in New Jersey.1The article also reports briefly on
similar studies of data from (1) the arbitration of discharge grievances, (2) the arbitration
of court-annexed disputes in Pittsburgh, and (3) the settlement of child custody disputes in
California. All of these data provide evidence that the parties face strong individual incen-
tives to obtain legal representation. Whether these incentives lead to excessive legal repre-
sentation that has no social benefit is discussed in the final section of the article. Using our
New Jersey data, we find some evidence that lawyers may well have improved outcomes by
moderating client biases early on in the history of the system. However, over time, the
parties slowly evolved to a noncooperative equilibrium where the use of lawyers becomes
nearly universal, despite the fact that agreeing not to hire lawyers is cheaper and does not
appear to alter arbitration outcomes.
II. Incentives for Noncooperation
The theoretical literature on the economics of litigation, particularly game theory applied
to law, is extensive. In contrast, there has been less empirical work, consisting of a few
experimental papers, on game theory and litigation and some empirical work in field
settings.2The main contribution of this article is to lay out a simple model of the role
lawyers play in dispute resolution, and empirically test whether the incentives present in
such systems generate a prisoner’s dilemma.
1A related, but more technical, analysis of New Jersey’s arbitration system can be found in Ashenfelter and Dahl
(2012).
2For a summary of theoretical models of negotiation and legal services, see Spier (2007). Prominent papers in this
literature include Katz (1988), Kerkmeester (1995), P’ng (1983), Reinganum and Wilde (1986), Rong (2012), and
Spier (1994). Experimental papers on game theory and litigation include Ashenfelter et al. (1992), Kritikos (2006),
and Plott and Coughlan (1997). Greiner and Pattanayak (2012) provide an example of empirical work in a field
setting.
400 Ashenfelter et al.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT