Land Value Taxation in Vancouver: Rent‐Seeking and the Tax Revolt

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12218
Published date01 January 2018
AuthorChristopher England
Date01 January 2018
Land Value Taxation in Vancouver: Rent-
Seeking and the Tax Revolt
By CHRISTOPHER ENGLAND*
ABSTRACT. At the beginning of t he 20
th
century, Vancouver obtained
international acclaim as a “single-tax” city. Supporters claimed that land
value taxation was responsible for the spectacular growth of the city.
Even critics believed that it had produced a building boom and
declining rents. Yet, over several decades, the system was scaled back
and ultimately ended in 1984. This article argues that the property tax
revolt can be understood with Mancur Olson’s model of collective
action. Property owners are better organized than other parties
impacted by housing policy because they have financial resources and
a salient economic concern in housing. Thus, the special interests of
property owners in higher values and unrestricted use prevailed over
the interests of tenants and prospective buyers. While the property tax
revolt was often articulated in the progressive language of ability to
pay, when confronted with progressive counterarguments, it collapsed
into explicit arguments for rent-seeking.
Introduction
A recent article in the Economist called land valuetaxation “ideal in the-
ory, elusive in practice” (Lucas 2015). The premise that land value taxa-
tion is politically unpalatable is not entirely borne out by the facts. It
has been established in some American cities, much of Western Canada,
Denmark, Germany, Hong Kong, Israel, Estonia, Holland, Australia,
and New Zealand (England 2015). Most of the places that have estab-
lished land value taxation seem to have experienced some of the pur-
ported benefits. Anecdotally, they appear to have well-performing and
*PhD in U.S. History from Georgetown University. Experience includes: fellow at
the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, instructor at the University of Wisconsin at Madi-
son, and researcher at the Wisconsin Historical Society. Email: Christopher.England@
Wisconsinhistory.org. The research for this article was generously supported by the
Lincoln Institute of Land Policy. The author appreciates the Institute for its support
and its guidance in the development of this article.
American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 77, No. 1 (January, 2018).
DOI: 10.1111/ajes.12218
V
C2018 American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Inc.
relatively egalitarian economies with high rates of development. Quan-
titative analysis has established more definitively that land value taxa-
tion is associated with higher rates of construction and population
density (Plassmann and Tideman 2000; Cho et al. 2013; Lyytik
ainen
2009). Yet, despite land value taxation taking hold in several countries,
it has, in each instance, slowly lost ground. Furthermore, the adoption
of the tax has slowed to a crawl since the days when Henry George
inspired a period of globalenthusiasm for it.
To understand the backlash against land value taxation it is worth-
while to consider the question of property tax revolts more generally.
While property taxes and land value taxes differ in important ways, the
average voter often has little or no sense for those differences. Our
understanding of property tax revolts is dominated by California’s 1978
referendum campaign for Proposition 13. This, it has been argued, was
precipitated in part by racial resentment. Furthermore, more accurate
assessment methods accentuated shocks from rapid home price inflation
(Martin 2008; Self 2003). More generally, anti-property-tax sentiment
correlates to racial heterogeneity and often draws on a sense of white
identity that transcends traditional notions of class (O’Brien 2017; Walsh
2016). However, if heightened racial animus and shocks in assessment
spur animosity toward the property tax, they only seem to exacerbate
innate problems. Proposition 13 hardly ended in the racially tinged Cali-
fornia suburbs that birthed it; two-thirds of states subsequently estab-
lished limitations on the property tax. Glenn Fisher (1996) studied the
history of the property tax in Kansas over a century and found that tax
revolts were a routine and periodic feature of state politics. Property
taxes are systematically disliked because of their “salience .” They are
generally paid directly by the taxpayer, ratherthan through withholdings
or indirect collection. Where property taxes are paid in escrow and are
thus less noticeable, opposition is lower (Cabral and Hoxby 2012).
One of the hotly contested questions about the property tax revolt is
the extent to which it can be construed as progressive. Proposition 13
fed into the conservative movement and helped carry Ronald Reagan
to the White House (Nathan 1981). Property tax limitation increased
real estate prices and skewed wealth significantly to whites (Hoyt et al.
2011; Martin and Beck 2017). However, property tax limits were typi-
cally established directly by voters in referendums that gave them
The American Journal of Economics and Sociology60
a populist hue. Some of the earliestadvocates of tax limitation included
labor unions and progressive leaders who argued that the system failed
to live up to the principle of ability to pay. Some advocated replacing
property taxes with income taxes that had a more progressive distribu-
tional outcome. Others argued for adopting “circuit breakers” that
reduced the burden of the property tax on low-income citizens (Martin
2008; Mound 2015; Self 2003.)
The Vancouver, British Columbia example, examined below, reinfor-
ces that ability-to-pay arguments were frequently leveled against the
property tax. However, they were often disingenuous and subtly reac-
tionary. Vancouver is a special case because it had long operated on a
system of land value taxation (LVT) based on the utopian ideas of
Henry George. This created an unusually robust progressive backlash
against tax revolts. Experts provided strong testimony that the burden
of the tax fell disproportionately on the wealthy and that the tax pro-
vided numerous benefits to the community, including lower housing
costs, higher rates of construction, more efficient use of space, better
public services, and greater social mobility. Ability-to-pay attacks on the
property tax wiltedwhen confronted with this opposition. Instead, they
resolved themselves into blunt statements that property rights super-
seded community interests. Robert Murray Haig, one of the leading
spokesmen for the “ability-to-pay” principle, demonstrated that these
reactionary tendencies were baked into his philosophy. Haig’s studies
of LVT in Canada largely confirmed the reputed benefits, but argued
against the tax because owners of property did not always have the liq-
uid assets that would make them “able to pay.” In effect, he opposed
wealth taxes for precisely the reason that Thomas Piketty (2014) argues
for them: they can encourage the redistribution of property when
wealth does not produce enough income to justify its tenure.
I argue that the opposition to land value taxation in Vancouver did
not arise primarily over questions related to its progressive distribu-
tional effects. Instead, it was best characterized by the type of group
behavior that Mancur Olson identified with“rent-seeking.” Olson asked
how it was that in democratic societies most policy decisions favor spe-
cial interests over the public good. He concluded that organizational
group behavior naturally favored small groups skimming money from
larger ones. In a zero-sum game, these small groups would obtain
Land Value Taxation in Vancouver 61

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT