Land Use in the 21st Century: Contributing to the Global Public Good

Published date01 May 2017
Date01 May 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12295
Land Use in the 21st Century: Contributing to the
Global Public Good
Thomas W. Hertel*
Abstract
This paper focuses on the evolution of global public goods related to the world’s land resources over the
course of the 21st century, their potential impacts on the world’s poorest households, as well as prospects
for policy interventions aimed at enhancing these outcomes. It begins with global scale projections to
2100 of land use and associated goods and services, including food, fuel, timber, greenhouse gas
emissions, carbon sequestration and biodiversity. This is followed by in-depth discussion of each of these
services and the challenges of providing these public goods in suff‌icient quantities to advance societal
welfareespecially that of the world’s poorest households. The paper concludes with a discussion of
policies aimed at promoting the provision of land-based public goods and how they could be altered to
be more pro-poor. Within this context, the paper argues that access to geospatial analysis tools and
information on climate, land use and tenure, poverty and environmental indicators will become
increasingly valuable to both public and private decision makers.
1. Introduction and Historical Perspective
Land is arguably the world’s most important natural resource. It provides a host of
public and private goods and humankind has played a large role in shaping its
evolution over the millennia. Ramankutty et al. (2006) point out that people have
been involved in inducing land cover change since the beginning of human history.
Today, about one-third of the world’s land cover is devoted to agriculture, one-
third to forests and one-f‌ifth to savannas, grasslands and shrublands (Ramankutty,
2010). While the global area devoted to crops has changed only modestly in the
past 50 years, the distribution of these croplands has changed much more
dramatically (Ramankutty et al., 2008). Indeed, global land cover change
accelerated to unprecedented levels during this time period (Lepers et al., 2005),
and this, in turn, has had consequences for the associated ecosystem services
available at local, regional and global scales. Much of the cropland expansion
during the past half century has been in the tropics (Ramankutty et al., 2002).
There is evidence that the cropland expansion in the tropics has come at the
expense of closed tropical forests (Gibbs et al., 2010). These areas are particularly
rich in biodiversity as well as carbon (West et al., 2010).
The question of global adequacy of the world’s land resources to meet continuing
growth in demand for food, f‌iber, fuel and other ecosystem services has important
implications for the world’s poor. The bulk of the world’s poor reside in rural areas,
and many of these households still “live off the land” in one way or another. Many
are smallholder farmers, others are employed in agriculture or forestry activities
*Hertel (Corresponding author): Department of Agricultural Economics, Purdue University, West
Lafayette, IN, 47907-1145, USA. E-mail: hertel@purdue.edu.
The copyright line for this article was changed on 09 February 2017 after original online publication.
Review of Development Economics, 21(2), 213–236, 2017
DOI:10.1111/rode.12295
©2016 UNU-WIDER. Review of Development Economics Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike License, which permits use
and distribution in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited, the use is non-commercial and the content is offered under
identical terms.
and others still rely on hunting and gathering for a signif‌icant portion of their
income and/or sustenance (Cavendish, 2000). Efforts to increase the provision of
land-based public goods will affect these households directly, when they are either
displaced (e.g. by a nature preserve) or when they are paid for providing these
services themselves (e.g. for carbon sequestration or forest conservation). There are
also important indirect effects that arise when the overall availability of land is
altered, thereby affecting food prices and rural employment opportunities.
This paper begins with an overview of how global land use and the associated
public and private goods and services are likely to change over the course of the
21st century. It then offers an in-depth analysis of key, land-based public goods
(Table 1), including carbon sequestration, bioenergy, biodiversity, and institutions
to facilitate climate adaptation, including information and analysis tools to adapt to
the changing environment. The paper focuses on areas where under-provision of
these public goods is likely and, in such cases, it discusses the potential for public
policies, research and development assistance to enhance their provision.
2. The Evolving Global Supply and Demand for Land-based Goods and
Services in the Twenty-f‌irst Century
Before examining the specif‌ic public goods associated with global land use, it is
useful to step back and evaluate how we expect global land use to change over the
coming century. What are the fundamental drivers behind global land use and the
associated goods and services? Towards this end, we draw on projections for global
land use change and land-based greenhouse gas (GHG) emissionsover the 21st
century developed by Steinbuks and Hertel (2016) using the FABLE (Forestry
Agriculture Biofuels Landuse and Environment) model. FABLE is a discrete,
dynamic, partial equilibrium optimization model that runs at global scale and
characterizes long run competition for land between food, biofuel, forest products,
carbon sequestration and other land-based ecosystem services. FABLE allocates long
run global land uses in order to maximize the discounted social value obtained from
these land-based goods and services, subject to available technology and biophysical
constraints, including the global land endowment and explicit growth functions for
food crops, bioenergy crops and forests, by vintage. FABLE is “forward-looking,”
which means that optimal land use change today is inf‌luenced by expectations of
developments in the future, including energy prices, population and income growth,
new technologies and government policies. In the baseline scenario, real fossil fuel
costs rise at an annual rate of 3% (Energy Information Agency, 2010), population
growth slows, plateauing at 10 billion people in 2100 (Bloom, 2011), global per capita
income grows at about 2%/year and, in the absence of climate mitigation policies,
GHG accumulation in the atmosphere causes global temperatures over agricultural
areas to rise at an average rate of 0.3 degC/decade (Intergovernmental Panel on
Climate Change (IPCC), 2007). (Given their inherent uncertainty, alternative paths
for these underlying drivers of land use change will be explored later on.)
Figure 1(a) reports the evolving allocation of global agricultural and forest land
use over the 21st century, according to the FABLE baseline. Area devoted to food
production continues to rise to 2040, as demand growth, driven by rising population
and dietary upgrading, outpaces productivity growth. However, by 2040, the
combination of slowing population growth, improved productivity and competition
from second generation biofuels, results in cropland devoted to food production
declining after 2040, ending the century 12% below current levels. In contrast to
214 Thomas W. Hertel
©2016 UNU-WIDER. Review of Development Economics Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT