Land rental markets and rural poverty dynamics in Northern Ethiopia: Panel data evidence using survival models

AuthorStein Holden,Hosaena Ghebru
Published date01 February 2019
Date01 February 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12548
REGULAR ARTICLE
Land rental markets and rural poverty dynamics in
Northern Ethiopia: Panel data evidence using
survival models
Hosaena Ghebru
1
|
Stein Holden
2
1
International Food Policy Research
Institute, Washington, DC, USA
2
Norwegian University of Life Sciences,
Ås, Norway
Correspondence
Hosaena Ghebru, International Food
Policy Research Institute, Development
Strategy and Governance Division, 1201
Eye Street, NW, Washington, DC 20005.
Email: hosaena.ghebru@cgiar.org
Funding information
The United States Agency for
International Development (USAID); The
CGIAR Research Program on Policies,
Institutions, and Markets, led by IFPRI.;
The Centre for Land Tenure Studies and
the School of Economics and Business at
Norwegian University of Life Sciences
Abstract
There is growing interest in understanding the links
between land reforms, land markets, and poverty reduc-
tion in Africa. The study uses fourwave panel data from
the northern highlands of Ethiopia to assess the dynamics
of rural poverty taking into account the status of partici-
pation of rural households in the land rental market.
Applying both nonparametric (KaplanMeier estimator)
and semiparametric survival models that control for dura-
tion dependence of poverty transition, results show partic-
ipation and degree of participation on the supply side of
the tenancy market (landlords) have highly significant and
positive effect on the chances of escaping poverty while
the same cannot be said about the demand side of the
tenancy market (tenants). The empirical evidence also
confirms that households headed by older and literate
people have relatively larger exit rates from poverty as
compared with households headed by younger and illiter-
ate ones. Though transacting farmers may engage them-
selves in winwin rental arrangements by the time they
join the tenancy market, results indicate that gains are
unequal as those tenants who enter the markets from low
economic leverage (were poor) are liable to face a lower
margin of net gains, which may limit their ability to move
out of poverty.
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12548
Rev Dev Econ. 2019;23:131154. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode © 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
131
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Throughout the SubSaharan Africa, access to rural land and its potential in reducing rural poverty
has long been a subject of high policy agenda and research interest (Haggblade & Hazell, 1988;
Holden, Otsuka, & Place, 2008a,b; Warriner, 1969). The increasing trend in the number of Afri-
cans living in poverty has made the focus of governments, development partners, and the
researcher communities towards piloting propoorland policies (Cotula, Toulmin, & Hesse,
2004; Holden et al., 2008). The slow progress in redistributive and other land tenure reforms (land
rights formalization/regularization) has encouraged the consideration of land market transactions as
viable options (Adams, 2004) and caused major multilateral agencies like the World Bank to
rethink the role even temporary access via land (rental) markets can play in agricultural growth
and poverty reduction (Deininger & Binswanger, 1999).
The fact that land rental markets have relatively lower transaction costs than land sales markets
(Chamberlin & RickerGilbert, 2016; Deininger & Binswanger, 1999; Jin & Jayne, 2013;Sadoulet,
Murgai, & De Janvry, 2001; Zimmerman & Carter, 1999) has given way to recognition of the crit-
ical role these markets can play as a means for providing the poor with access to land. Rightly so,
since the turn of the millennium, land policies and legal reforms to liberalize and formalize land
rental markets have been top policy agenda in many countries of Africa South of the Sahara
(Cotula et al., 2004; Holden et al., 2008).
There is a large body of empirical literature on the welfare implications of land access and land
distribution in Africa (Carter & May, 1999;Haggblade & Hazell, 1988; Jayne, Zulu, Kajoba, & Weber,
2008; Jayne et al. , 2003; Karugia, OluochKosura, Nyikal, Odumbe, & Marenya, 2006; Rigg, 2006), but
relativelyfew studies on the povertyreducing impacts of land rental markets. Despite the e arlier skeptical
view on the performance of land markets (Binswanger, Deininger, & Feder, 1995; Carter, 1988; Lipton,
1993; Sjaastad, 2003), empirical studies from Rwanda (Andre & Platteau, 1998; Blarel, 2004), Ghana
(MigotAdholla, Benneh, Place, & Atsu, 1994; Otsuka, Quisumbing, Payongayong, & Aidoo, 2003),
Kenya (Jin & Jayne, 2013; Muraoka, Jin, & Jayne, 2018; Yamano, Place, Nyangena, Wanjiku, &
Otsuka, 2008), Ethiopia (Deininger, Ali, & Alemu, 2008; Ghebru & Holden, 2008; Holden & Bezabih,
2008; Kassie & Holden, 2008), and Malawi (Holden, Kaarhus, & Lunduka, 2006; Lunduka, Holden, &
Øygard, 2008) show that land rental markets contribute to more equitable operational holding between
the poor and the rich. In contrast with these, studies from Ethiopia (Bezabih & Holden, 2006; Holden &
Ghebru, 2006; Kassie & Holden, 2006), Malawi and Zambia (Chamberlin & RickerGilbert, 2016),
Madagascar (Bellmare, 2006), Tunisia (Laffont & Matoussi, 1995) and Eritrea (Tikabo & Holden, 2003)
reveal land rental markets role in transferring land from relatively poorer landlords to wealthier tenants.
What is empirically common with these studies (with the exception of Chamberlin & RickerGilbert,
2016) is that they make deductions about the povertyreducing effects of land rental markets by
analyzing the allocative efficiency and equity implic ations of such markets.
While it is true that allocative efficiency and equity implications of land rental markets can be
implicative to suggest the povertyreducing potential, the story remains incomplete unless nonland
resource endowments are also considered. Hence, it is not always true to conceive the landless
(landconstrained) as the poorest (Chamberlin & RickerGilbert, 2016). The rural landless in Africa
(mostly young and inexperienced in farming) may find alternative sources of income, either from
agricultural labor and/or employment in the rural nonfarm economy. Particularly, in countries with
an egalitarian land ownership distribution (like, Ethiopia), the poorest members of society can be
those with few capital or nonland assets and constrained access to microfinance credit. In other
words, the conventional approach of using own land holding for characterization of poverty may
not only be less informative but also misleading. See (Chamberlin & RickerGilbert, 2016).
132
|
GHEBRU AND HOLDEN

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT