Labor Skills and Foreign Investment in a Dynamic Economy: Estimating the Knowledge‐capital Model for Singapore

AuthorGnanaraj Chellaraj,Aaditya Mattoo,Keith E. Maskus
Date01 November 2013
Published date01 November 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12055
Labor Skills and Foreign Investment in a Dynamic
Economy: Estimating the Knowledge-capital Model
for Singapore
Gnanaraj Chellaraj, Keith E. Maskus, and Aaditya Mattoo*
Abstract
Singapore is an interesting example of how the pattern of foreign investment changes with economic devel-
opment. This paper studies inbound and outbound investment between Singapore and a sample of industri-
alized and developing countries over the period 1984–2007. Singapore’s investments from industrialized
nations shifted into skill-seeking activities, while its investments in developing countries became concen-
trated in labor-seeking production. The knowledge-capital model is used to analyze the determinants of
these shifts. The estimates suggest that a 10% increase in Singapore’s skill differences with developing
countries resulted in a 15.2% increase in outbound stocks of investment to the average recipient nation. A
10% decline in skill differences with industrialized countries after 1995 resulted in a 3.6% increase in
inbound stocks from the average parent nation.
1. Introduction
In this paper, we explore the influence of skills on foreign investment in Singapore, a
small, newly industrialized country (NIC). Singapore has been successful in attracting
foreign direct investment (FDI) during its period of rapid economic development. It
has also experienced significant deepening of its human capital stock during this
period. It is possible that the rapid growth of its skill endowments has been a signifi-
cant factor in attracting foreign investment. One framework within which to analyze
the role of skill endowments on FDI location is the knowledge-capital (KK) model.
This model has been applied to data in a number of industrialized countries, including
the USA (Carr et al., 2001). The KK model has, however, not been estimated for any
NIC.
From the time of independence in 1965, until the late 1970s, multinational enter-
prises (MNEs) invested in Singapore because of low wages (Low, 1999). As a result of
high economic growth and escalating wages, the government developed strategies to
attract high end FDI by focusing on developing the skills of the population. Between
1984 and 1998, Singapore rapidly closed its skills gap with most industrialized coun-
tries through the expansion of higher education and by facilitating the inflow of
* Maskus: School of Arts and Sciences and Department of Economics, University of Colorado, 275 UCB,
Boulder, CO 80309, USA. Tel: +1-303-492-7588; Fax: +1-303-492-8960; E-mail: keith.maskus
@colorado.edu. Chellaraj: Trade and Integration Unit, Development Economic Research Group, World
Bank, Washington DC 20433, USA. Mattoo: Trade and Integration Unit, Development Economic
Research Group, World Bank, Washington DC 20433, USA. We wish to thank James Markusen, Caroline
Freund, David Tarr, Shiva Makki, Sumner LaCroix, Shawn Arita, and other seminar participants at the
World Bank and the University of Hawaii and the anonymous reviewers for their comments, and Thamnu
Sishobhon, Polly Means, Q-H Zhao and Josette Vizmanons for their technical assistance. Financial support
from the Multi-Donor Trust Fund of the Development Economics Research Group at the World Bank is
also gratefully acknowledged.
Review of Development Economics, 17(4), 627–643, 2013
DOI:10.1111/rode.12055
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
foreign talent.1The rapid economic development of Singapore may be partly attrib-
uted to these policies (Kee and Hoon, 2005).
Singapore transformed itself from a small, labor-abundant developing nation in the
mid-1970s to a larger, though still small (in terms of gross domestic product (GDP)),
skill-abundant NIC today. The nature of its inward foreign investment should have
shifted from a labor-seeking orientation to a skill-seeking orientation, while its
outward investments in developing countries should have become more focused on
low-wage locations. These primary questions have not been empirically studied,
which is the task we undertake here.
2. The Knowledge-capital Model and Prior Empirical Literature
Since Markusen (1984) and Helpman (1984), the general-equilibrium theory of MNEs
has focused on two motivations for FDI: to access markets to circumvent trade fric-
tions (horizontal FDI) and to employ low-wage labor for labor-intensive assembly
portions of the production process (vertical FDI). In the former case, multiple plants
making similar goods are located in different markets and produce either for local
markets or regional exports. In the latter, headquarters are split from assembly, and
goods are traded in different stages of fabrication.
Theoretical Overview
The general-equilibrium KK model of FDI (Markusen, 2002) makes three principal
assumptions. First, services of knowledge-based activities can be geographically sepa-
rated from production and supplied to production facilities at low cost. Second, these
knowledge-intensive activities are skilled-labor intensive relative to production.
These assumptions generate incentives for firms to fragment production into vertical
phases, locating R&D activities where skilled labor is abundant and production where
unskilled labor is well endowed. They also offer an incentive to locate production in
large markets if there are significant scale economies at the plant level, generating
horizontal or market-seeking FDI. The third assumption is that knowledge-based
assets are inherently joint inputs and may be deployed simultaneously at multiple pro-
duction facilities. This characteristic generates firm-level scale economies and sup-
ports horizontal investments in facilities that produce the same products in different
locations.
Specifically, the KK model combines factor endowments with complex economies
of scale to explain FDI location decisions. It presumes two countries and two homo-
geneous factors, unskilled labor and skilled labor, which cannot move across borders.
The model also assumes two homogeneous goods, one of which is labor intensive and
subject to constant returns to scale. The other is skilled-labor intensive and demon-
strates increasing returns to scale (IRS) at the plant level. Firms in this sector can
separate headquarters services from production plants, which may be located in either
the home or foreign countries, or both. These services can be shared across plants,
which support firm-level economies of scale in this sector. Finally, there are transport
costs in trading goods and fixed costs of investing in a new plant.
The model predicts the potential existence of several firm types in the IRS good in
equilibrium. First, there may be national firms that operate a single plant and head-
quarters in one country and may export to the other. Second, horizontal MNEs main-
tain plants in both countries but have headquarters in a single location. Finally,
vertical MNEs operate headquarters in one nation and a single plant in the other
country.
628 Gnanaraj Chellaraj, Keith E. Maskus, and Aaditya Mattoo
© 2013 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT