Labor Noncompete Agreements: Tool for Economic Efficiency or Means to Extract Value from Workers?

Published date01 December 2021
AuthorDavid J. Balan
Date01 December 2021
DOI10.1177/0003603X211045443
Subject MatterArticle
Article
Labor Noncompete Agreements:
Tool for Economic Efficiency or
Means to Extract Value from
Workers?
David J. Balan*
Abstract
A number of theoretical arguments have been offered in favor of noncompete provisions in labor
agreements. While there has been considerable empirical research on the effects of those provisions,
there has been little direct evaluation of the arguments themselves. In this article, I lay out and evaluate
three commonly heard arguments, namely, (1) the voluntary nature of labor agreements justifies a
strong inference that the terms of those agreements, including noncompete provisions, are beneficial
for both workers and firms and that they are economically efficient, 2(A) noncompetes facilitate
efficient knowledge transfer from firms to workers, and 2(B) noncompetes encourage efficient firm-
sponsored investment in worker training. These arguments, though not entirely without merit, mostly
do not survive close scrutiny, and in fact such scrutiny reveals strong arguments that point in the
opposite direction. In addition, noncompetes may cause important additional harms that are not
measured in conventional economic research.
Keywords
noncompetes, labor noncompetes, postemployment restrictive covenants, PERCs
I. Introduction
Noncompete provisions in labor agreements have become widespread in the United States.
1
In recent
years, empirical researchers have studied the effects of noncompetes on wo rker mobility, hiring,
entrepreneurship, investment, innovation, wages, and other economic outcomes. This research agenda
is quite new, and determining the true, causative effect of noncompetes on those outcomes is
* Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC, USA
Corresponding Author:
David J. Balan, Federal Trade Commission, Washington, DC 20580, USA.
Email: dbalan@ftc.gov
1. See Evan P. Starr et al, Noncompete Agreements in the US Labor Force, 64 J.L. & ECON. 53–84 (2021); ALEXANDER J. S.
COLVIN & HEIDI SHIERHOLZ, NONCOMPETE AGREEMENTS (Econ. Policy Inst. 2019).
The Antitrust Bulletin
2021, Vol. 66(4) 593–608
ªThe Author(s) 2021
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0003603X211045443
journals.sagepub.com/home/abx
challenging. But recognizing these limitations, the evidence as it exists today, while somewhat mixed,
generally shows noncompetes to be economically harmful and not beneficial.
This empirical evidence must be interpreted in light of the strength of the theoretical arguments for
or against noncompetes. If there were strong theoretical arguments in their favor, the empirical
evidence accumulated to date may not be sufficient to convincingly demonstrate that noncompetes
are harmful on balance. But if the theoretical arguments in favor of noncompetes are weak, or if there
are strong theoretical arguments against them, then the theory and the empirical evidence would both
point in the same direction, strongly indicating that noncompetes are likely to be harmful and even
more strongly indicating that they are unlikely to be highly beneficial.
2
The purpose of this article is to provide a critical evaluation of those theoretical arguments. There
are three major arguments that are commonly offered in favor of noncompetes, namely, (1) the
voluntary nature of labor agreements justifies a strong inference that the terms of those agreements,
including noncompete provisions, are mutually beneficial to workers and firms and that they are
economically efficient in the sense of increasing total economic surplus, 2(A) noncompetes facilitate
efficient knowledge transfer from firms to workers, and 2(B) noncompetes encourage efficient firm-
sponsored investment in worker training.
There is a substantial body of literature that makes or develops these theoretical arguments.
3
The
structure of this article is to enumerate, explain, and respond to these arguments one by one.
4
To summarize my conclusions, these arguments sound plausible and have some limited merit, but
all three largely fail upon close scrutiny, and in fact such scrutiny reveals strong arguments to the
contrary. This theoretical conclusion, combined with the empirical evidence (discussed below) that
mostly finds noncompetes to be harmful, together constitute strong reason to believe that noncompetes
are in fact harmful, and even stronger reason to believe that they are not highly beneficial such that
restricting or banning them would risk major economic damage.
5
Moreover, noncompetes may cause harms that are not generally within the purview of economics
and that are not normally studied in economic research. A worker who is bound by a noncompete has a
large barrier to leaving a firm (on top of other barriers that likely exist), rendering them less able to
avoid or resist mistreatment at their firm, including true exploitation or abuse by a predatory employer
2. In Bayesian terms, if the theoretical arguments in favor of noncompetes are strong, then the priors would be strong that
noncompetes are highly beneficial, and it would take a large amount of contrary evidence to overturn those priors. But if
those arguments are weak, and/or if there are strong arguments that noncompetes are harmful, then the priors would be that
noncompetes are harmful (or at least not highly beneficial), and it would take a large amount of contrary evidence to overturn
those priors.
3. Perhaps the clearest exposition of Argument #1 is at David D. Friedman, Non-Competition Agreements: Some Alternative
Explanations, daviddfriedman.com, April 2, 1991, http://www.daviddfriedman.com/Academic/non-comp/Non-
Competition.html. See also Maureen B. Callahan, Post-Employment Restraint Agreements: A Reassessment, 52 U. CHI.
L. REV. 703–28 (1985). Articles that advance Argument #2(A) include Jonathan M. Barnett & Ted Sichelman, The Case for
Noncompetes, 87 U. CHI. L. REV. 953–1049 (2020); and Brandon S. Long, Protecting Employer Investment in Training:
Noncompetes vs. Repayment Agreements, 54 DUKE L.J. 1295–320 (2005). Articles that advance Argument #2(B) include
Paul H. Rubin & Peter Shedd, Human Capital and Covenants Not to Compete,10J.L
EGAL STUD. 93–110 (1981); and Long,
supra note 3.
4. Points similar to some of those made in this article can be found in Eric A. Posner, The Antitrust Challenge to Covenants Not
to Compete in Employment Contracts, 83 ANTITRUST L.J. 165–200 (2020) and in the survey articles referenced in note 6.
See also NON-COMPETE CONTRACTS: ECONOMIC EFFECTS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS (U.S. DEPT OF THE
TREASURY, OFFICE OF ECON. POLICY 2016); NON-COMPETE AGREEMENTS: ANALYSIS OF THE USAGE,
POTENTIAL ISSUES, AND STATE RESPONSES (The White House 2016).
5. Returning to the Bayesian framing from note 2, the conclusion of this article is that the correct priors are that noncompetes are
likely to be harmful and are very unlikely to be highly beneficial. Given these priors, the existing empirical evidence provides
little grounds for updating. In other words, there is a consonance rather than a tension between the empirical evidence and the
theory.
594 The Antitrust Bulletin 66(4)

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT