Jurists, Clerics, and Merchants: The Rise of Learned Law in Medieval Europe and its Impact on Economic Growth

Published date01 June 2014
AuthorHans‐Bernd Schäfer,Alexander J. Wulf
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jels.12041
Date01 June 2014
Jurists, Clerics, and Merchants: The Rise of
Learned Law in Medieval Europe and its
Impact on Economic Growth
Hans-Bernd Schäfer and Alexander J. Wulf*
Between the years 1200 and 1600, economic development in Catholic Europe gained
momentum. By the end of this period, per-capita income levels were well above the income
levels in all other regions of the world. We relate this unique development to the resurrec-
tion of Roman law, the rise of canon law, and the establishment of law as a scholarly and
scientific discipline taught in universities. We test two competing hypotheses on the impact
of these processes on economic growth in medieval Europe. The first conjecture is that the
spread of substantive Roman law was conducive to the rise of commerce and economic
growth. The second and competing conjecture is that growth occurred not as a result of the
reception of substantive Roman law but because of the rational, scientific, and systemic
features of Roman and canon law and the training of jurists in the newly established
universities (Verwissenschaftlichung). This gave the law throughout Europe an innovative
flexibility, which also influenced merchant law (lex mercatoria), and customary law. Using
data on the population of more than 200 European cities as a proxy for per-capita income,
we find that an important impact for economic development was not primarily the content
of Roman law, but the rise of law faculties in universities and the emergence of a legal
method developed by glossators and commentators in their interpretation and systematiza-
tion of the sources of Roman law (Corpus Juris Civilis, Digests) and canon law. The endeavor
to extract general normative conclusions from these sources led to abstraction, methodol-
ogy, and the rise of law as a scholarly discipline. Wherever law faculties were founded
anywhere in Europe, jurists learned new legal concepts and skills that were unknown before
and conducive for doing business.
I. Introduction
Has the unique legal development that began around the year 1080 at the University of
Bologna and changed the concept of law throughout Europe had an impact on economic
*Address correspondence to Hans-Bernd Schäfer, Bucerius Law School, Jungiusstr. 6, 20355 Hamburg, Germany;
email: hans-bernd.schaefer@law-school.de. Wulf is at Bucerius Law School, Hamburg and SRH Hochschule, Berlin.
We thank Michael Funke, Dirk Heirbaut, Reinhard Zimmermann, Tilman Repgen, Vincenzo Colli, Benjamin
Veal, Claus Ott, Peter Behrens, Hein Kötz, Karsten Schmidt, Robert Cooter, Marcus Schadl, Herrmann Pünder,
Roland Vaubel, Jaroslaw Beldowski, Marco Fabbri, participants of workshops where we presented the article, and two
anonymous reviewers for valuable comments and suggestions. Our special thanks goes to Axel Moeller, who helped
us with the empirical data and graphs. We are very indebted to Ted Eisenberg, who made substantial suggestions as
to the models used, as well as to Jim Gordley, who provided us with valuable additional information on the law and
legal scholarship in the Middle Ages. All errors are the authors’ responsibility.
bs_bs_banner
Journal of Empirical Legal Studies
Volume 11, Issue 2, 266–300, June 2014
266
growth? Some legal historians regard this process, which culminated in the establishment
of a systematic, rational, and sophisticated body of law, as one of the greatest cultural
achievements in Europe.1It gave rise to the resurrection and reception of Roman law in
some countries and to the establishment of an equally sophisticated system of canon law in
all of Catholic Europe and later its development to a jus commune. Little is known,
however, whether and to what extent this cultural achievement contributed to the eco-
nomic growth over the same period, in which Western Europe became the most opulent
world region, long before the growth processes in the 18th century that culminated in the
Industrial Revolution (see Figure 1).2
We show how the spread of Roman law and the spread of learned lawyers trained in
universities influenced city growth. Our panel study spans from the year 1200 to 1600 and
uses data on city population, the proliferation of universities with law departments in
Europe, and the extent to which Roman substantive and procedural law was received in the
different European regions. It also includes other variables with an important effect on the
population of cities, such as, for instance, the population numbers in Western European
countries and regions, the catastrophic bubonic plague in the 14th century, and the degree
of political and economic freedom in the different regions of Europe.
1H.J. Berman, Law and Revolution. The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition (1983); P. Stein, Roman Law in
European History (2009); T. Repgen, Ius Commune, in H.P. Haferkamp & T. Repgen, eds., Usus modernus
pandectarum. Römisches Recht, Deutsches Recht und Naturrecht in der Frühen Neuzeit. Klaus Luig zum 70.
Geburtstag 157–73 (2007).
2The GDP per-capita estimates since the year 1 A.D. by Angus Maddison show that during the Middle Ages Western
Europe, especially Northern Italy and Flanders, broke out of the general world development and that most regions
of Western Europe achieved per-capita income levels well and significantly above all other world regions in the year
1500. See A. Maddison, Historical Statistics (2003).
Figure 1: Per-capita GDP 1000–1600, in 1990 dollars.
Source: Maddison, A. (2003) Historical Statistics. Paris: OECD.
Jurists, Clerics, and Merchants 267
The article is organized as follows. First we present some well-established facts about
the development of “learned law” in the newly established universities. We proceed to
present hypotheses of legal historians on the impact of this development on the economy.
The next section describes our model with the population number of cities as a proxy for
per-capita income as the dependent variable and with variables on the spread of Roman law
and the spread of law faculties as independent variables. We also correct for several other
factors that might have had an influence on city population in the relevant regions and
periods. We then present the results of the study, for which we use, among others, a fixed
effects model. The most important finding is a significant positive correlation between the
number of citizens in a particular city and the number of universities in a circle of 300
kilometers around the city. In the last section we deal with the causational link between
these two variables. We find some evidence that the arrow of causation goes from the rise
of universities and learned law to the growth of cities—that is, for a supply-side develop-
ment. However, a causational link in the other direction, driven by the demand of flour-
ishing cities, cannot be excluded. The combined development of learned law and
economic growth was arguably a kind of intertwined medieval Silicon Valley effect, with a
demand for new law from the emerging merchant cities and a supply from learned lawyers,
who provided new and formerly unknown legal products. This had an impact on the
economic rise of Western Europe.
II. Some Facts About a Quiet Cultural Revolution
A. A New Law
From the standard literature on legal history in medieval Europe we extract some facts that
are important for hypothesis building. During the early Middle Ages, some Roman law
survived in the kingdoms evolving in the territory of the West Roman Empire and in the
East Roman Empire, but in a form that was hardly conducive for economic growth. Roman
law, however, did not disappear completely. It remained alive in Italy, around the Gulf of
Lyon and in parts of Iberia.3These states continued to use legal practices that had evolved
during late antiquity when the principate, introduced by the Emperor Augustus, changed
into a “dominate.” The principate was still based on republican roots with limited powers of
the emperor and allowed a flourishing urban economy. The dominate of late antiquity
destroyed this backbone of the empire’s wealth by a ruthless system of taxes, services,
regulations, and requisitions for the main purpose of maintaining the bureaucracy and the
army.4
3We thank a referee for this information.
4F. Wieacker, The Importance of Roman Law for Western Civilization and Western Legal Thought, 4 Boston Coll.
Int’l & Comparative L. Rev. 257, 273 (1981); F. Wieacker, Privatrechtsgeschichte der Neuzeit unter besonderer
Berücksichtigung der deutschen Entwicklung (1996).
268 Schäfer and Wulf

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT