What In This Issue—A Message From The Editor

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-6622.1999.tb00654.x
Published date01 March 1999
Date01 March 1999
JOURNAL OF APPLIED CORPORATE FINANCE
2
What’s In This Issue—A Message From The Editor
Does capital structure matter? And,
if so, how and why does it matter?
Ever since Miller and Modigliani pub-
lished the first of their two famous
“irrelevance” propositions in 1958,
corporate finance scholars have found
it difficult to come up with definitive
answers to these questions.
Following the M & M propositions,
academic researchers in the 1960s
and ’70s turned their attention to
market “imperfections” that might
make firm value depend on capital
structure. The main suspects were
(1) a tax code that encourages debt
by making interest payments but not
dividends tax-deductible and (2) ex-
pected costs of financial distress that
rise with increasing amounts of debt.
Toward the end of the ’70s, there was
also discussion of “signaling” effects,
such as the tendency for stock prices
to fall significantly on the announce-
ment of new equity issues and to rise
on the news of stock buybacks. These
effects appeared to confirm the exist-
ence of large “information costs” that
could also influence financing choices
in predictable ways.
Such information costs took center
stage in the ongoing debate when, in
1984, MIT’s Stewart Myers devoted
his President’s address to the Ameri-
can Finance Association to what he
called “The Capital Structure Puzzle.”
The puzzle was this: Most academic
discussions of capital structure began
with the assumption that companies
making financing decisions are guided
by a target capital structure—a pro-
portion of debt to equity that manage-
ment aims to maintain, if not at all
times, then at least as a long-run
average. But the empirical evidence
suggested otherwise. Rather than ad-
hering to leverage targets, Myers ob-
served, most large U.S. public compa-
nies appear to follow a financing
“pecking order.” They use retained
earnings rather than external financ-
ing when possible; and if outside
capital is necessary, they issue debt
first and equity only as a last resort.
Based on the Darwinian principle
that efficient practices prevail, Myers
suggested that the pecking order
maximized firm value by minimizing
expected information costs—mainly,
it seems, by reducing to near zero the
probability that the firm would ever
have to issue equity.
The vulnerable point in the peck-
ing order is its apparent blanket en-
dorsement of financial “slack”; that is,
because internal funds are always
preferred to outside financing, the
model appears to imply that manag-
ers should hoard capital and so re-
duce their dependence on capital
markets. Then, in 1986, Harvard’s
Michael Jensen entered the capital
structure debate with a very different
message. Pointing to the success of
LBOs and leveraged acquisitions,
Jensen argued that, in the case of
mature companies, heavy debt fi-
nancing could add value by eliminat-
ing financial slack and thus curbing a
managerial tendency to overinvest in
industries with excess capacity. And,
as if to confirm that Jensen was on the
right track, the capital markets contin-
ued to supply large numbers of LBOs
and other leveraged deals during the
rest of the ’80s—a trend that, except
for a brief halt in the early ’90s, has
continued throughout this decade.
In the article that opens this issue,
Michael Barclay and Clifford Smith
argue that managerial incentives,
taxes, bankruptcy costs, and informa-
tion costs all appear to play important
roles in corporate financing decisions.
The key to reconciling the different
theories—and thus to solving the capi-
tal structure puzzle—lies in achieving
a better understanding of the relation
between corporate financing stocks
(leverage ratios) and flows (specific
choices between debt and equity).
According to the authors, the bulk of
the evidence on leverage ratios is
consistent with the idea that compa-
nies do have leverage targets, and
that such targets depend primarily on
one key variable: the company’s in-
vestment opportunities. As a general
rule, the larger the percentage of a
firm’s value that consists of intangible
“growth options,” the lower the lever-
age ratio. The authors explain this
pattern as follows: For high-growth
firms, the “underinvestment problem”
associated with heavy debt financing
can end up destroying significant
value. For mature companies, how-
ever, high leverage is likely to add
value by sheltering operating income
from taxes and controlling the mana-
gerial tendency to overinvest.
But if much of the evidence sug-
gests that companies do set leverage
targets, other research indicates that
firms often deviate widely from their
targets, particularly when experienc-
ing significant changes in profitabil-
ity. Although such findings are gener-
ally viewed as evidence that corpo-
rate managers do not have target
leverage ratios—or do not try very
hard to achieve them—Barclay and
Smith provide another interpretation:
Precisely because the information (and
other) costs of issuing riskier securi-
ties can be large, “even if companies
have target leverage ratios, there will
be an optimal deviation from those
targets—one that depends on the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT