Issue Scales, Information Cues, and the Proximity and Directional Models of Voter Choice

AuthorKevin K. Banda,Jonathan Kropko
DOI10.1177/1065912918760729
Date01 December 2018
Published date01 December 2018
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/1065912918760729
Political Research Quarterly
2018, Vol. 71(4) 772 –787
© 2018 University of Utah
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/1065912918760729
journals.sagepub.com/home/prq
Article
Introduction
Learning why citizens choose one candidate over another
is key to understanding how representative democracies
function. We cannot deduce the meaning of election out-
comes if we do not understand the reasons underlying
citizens’ choices. What drives citizens’ decision-making
processes when they make their vote choices, and what
role do candidates’ spatial positions on issues play in citi-
zens’ decisions?
According to the proximity theory of voting (e.g.,
Downs 1957), a citizen prefers a candidate whose posi-
tions exactly match her own. Given a choice between two
candidates, she should prefer the closer of the two, even
if the closer candidate is on the opposite side of the posi-
tional midpoint. A slightly left-of-center voter should
thus choose to vote for a slightly right-of-center candi-
date over a more distant far-left candidate. Under the
directional theory of voting (e.g., Rabinowitz and
Macdonald 1989), the citizen is not primarily concerned
with the candidates’ positions, but rather with the sides
that they occupy in issue space. The citizen should prefer
any reasonable candidate on her side relative to any can-
didate on the other side, even if the candidate on the other
side is closer to her own position.1 In this case, a slightly
left-of-center voter should choose the far-left candidate
over the closer slightly right-of-center candidate.2
These models represent fundamentally different ways
to conceive of voter behavior, and they have important
implications for candidate strategy. According to the
proximity model, a voter at the ideological midpoint is
principled and prefers the candidate who is closest to the
midpoint. Candidates should maximize their support by
locating themselves at the median issue position to com-
pete for the support of the median voter. Under the direc-
tional model, however, voters at the midpoint are
indifferent or ambivalent toward candidates at any posi-
tion and candidates maximize support by taking more
extreme positions on issues to better distinguish them-
selves from one another when competing for votes. We
should observe moderate candidates in a proximity
world3 and polarized candidates in a directional world.
This research joins a longstanding literature that com-
pares the proximity and directional models. Like other
scholars, we assume that an issue’s positions can be
graphed on a continuum from liberal to conservative. We
760729PRQXXX10.1177/1065912918760729Political Research QuarterlyKropko and Banda
research-article2018
1University of Virginia, Charlottesville, USA
2Texas Tech University, Lubbock, USA
Corresponding Author:
Jonathan Kropko, The Woodrow Wilson Department of Politics,
University of Virginia, 1540 Jefferson Park Avenue (JPA), S183 Gibson
Hall, Charlottesville, VA 22904.
Email: jkropko@virginia.edu
Issue Scales, Information Cues, and the
Proximity and Directional Models of
Voter Choice
Jonathan Kropko1 and Kevin K. Banda2
Abstract
One of the most important questions in the study of democratic politics centers on how citizens consider issues and
candidate positions when choosing whom to support in an election. The proximity and directional theories make
fundamentally different predictions about voter behavior and imply different optimal strategies for candidates, but
a longstanding literature to empirically adjudicate between the theories has yielded mixed results. We use a survey
experiment to show that the way that candidates’ issue positions are described can cue citizens to choose a candidate
that is preferred under the expectations of either the proximity or the directional theory. We find that directional
voting is more likely when the issue scale is understood to represent degrees of intensity with which either the liberal
or the conservative side of the issue is expressed and that proximity voting is more likely when an issue scale is
understood to be a range of policies.
Keywords
spatial voting, proximity theory, directional theory
Kropko and Banda 773
prompt participants to place themselves on this scale and
to choose between two candidates with positions on this
scale. We place the candidates such that one is the pre-
dicted choice of the proximity model and the other is the
predicted choice of the directional model. Unlike other
studies, which aim to choose the best single model for the
entire sample, we argue that not only are both proximity
and directional voters present in the electorate, but that
citizens can be cued to think about the issue in either way
depending on how the candidates’ positions are commu-
nicated. Proximity voting is more likely when an issue
scale is understood to be a range of policies, whereas
directional voting is more likely when the issue scale is
understood to represent degrees of intensity with which
either the liberal or the conservative side of the issue is
expressed. We use an experiment embedded in a nation-
ally representative survey to demonstrate these patterns.
In other words, both proximity and directional think-
ing are present in the electorate and the way in which the
candidates’ positions are communicated matters because
this information can cue individuals to use one model or
the other. Political discourse that emphasizes binary posi-
tions—the liberal side or the conservative side—and the
strength or purity of candidates’ positions encourages
directional thinking, which may aid extreme candidates.
Discourse that emphasizes the policy content of interme-
diate positions on an issue, on the contrary, encourages
proximity thinking, which in turn may benefit moderate
candidates.
Prior Comparisons of the Proximity
and Directional Models
Many substantive results are predicated on proximity vot-
ing and might not hold if the directional model is instead
correct. The proximity and directional models posit differ-
ent sets of incentives for candidates. The median voter
theorem (e.g., Black 1958; Downs 1957; Hotelling 1929),
for example, only holds under proximity voting. If voters
are directional, then the positions that maximize the
chance of electoral victory are the most extreme accept-
able positions for each issue on the same side as the
median voter rather than the precise positions of the
median voter herself. It follows that the elected represen-
tative in a single-member district, such as in elections for
the U.S. House of Representatives, may be much more
ideologically extreme than the median voter in the district.
Thus, this result may provide an explanation for polariza-
tion in Congress beyond the effects of redistricting and
primary elections. In addition, while proximity voting
implies that centrist parties in multiparty democracies—
where centrist is defined as adopting a platform that takes
moderate positions on most issues—can have stable con-
stituencies of moderate voters, directional theory predicts
that centrist parties are likely limited to unstable support
(Macdonald, Listhaug, and Rabinowitz 1991).
Given their differing implications, it is understandable
that the question of the relative validity of the proximity
and directional models has led to a voluminous literature.
Tomz and Van Houweling (2008) identify more than fifty
independent studies that attempt to adjudicate between the
models. The theories have been directly compared in their
ability to model observational data from American presi-
dential elections, American congressional elections,
Canadian and European elections, and even in how voters
are influenced by their spouses (see, for example, Adams,
Bishin, and Dow 2004; Blais et al. 2001; Cho and
Endersby 2003; Dow 1998; Iversen 1994; Johnston,
Fournier, and Jenkins 2000; Kenny and Jenner 2008;
Krämer and Rattinger 1997; Lewis and King 1999;
Macdonald, Listhaug, and Rabinowitz 1991; Macdonald,
Rabinowitz, and Listhaug 1995, 1998, 2001; Merrill 1994,
1995; Merrill and Grofman 1997; Montgomery and
Nyhan 2010; Platt, Poole, and Rosenthal 1992; Rabinowitz
and Macdonald 1989; Rabinowitz, Macdonald, and
Listhaug 1991; Westholm 1997).
Although the proximity and directional models are
empirically testable and comparable, the studies that com-
pare the models have not yielded a consensus. There are
four difficulties inherent in observational research that
obscure a valid and general comparison. First, a large
branch of this literature shows that the divergent results are
conditioned on different data coding decisions (e.g., Cho
and Endersby 2003; Gilljam 1997a, 1997b; Macdonald,
Rabinowitz, and Listhaug 1997, 1998; Merrill and
Grofman 1997; Pierce 1997). Given these concerns, Lewis
and King (1999, 32) conclude that “there exists essentially
no evidence . . . to distinguish between the two models”
using observational data. Second, none of these studies
allow for the possibility that directional and proximity vot-
ers coexist in the electorate (Morris and Rabinowitz 1997).
If some voters follow the directional model, and some vot-
ers follow the proximity model, then in the population we
expect to see a mixed model emerge as the best overall fit.
Third, few of the observational studies have attempted to
isolate the positions in ideological space for which the
proximity and directional models make different predic-
tions. A voter who reports the most extreme ideological
self-placement, for example, will prefer the most proxi-
mate candidate under both the proximity and directional
models. As a result, a large proportion of the samples used
in these studies contains observations that offer no guid-
ance on the relative validity of the models. Last, none of
these studies have considered how the information context
in which voters learn about candidate positions cues voters
to consider candidates in ways that are congruent with one
model or the other. We address these last two points in
more detail below.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT