Is stock return predictability of option‐implied skewness affected by the market state?

AuthorTong Suk Kim,Heewoo Park
Published date01 September 2018
Date01 September 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/fut.21921
1024 © 2018 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/fut J Futures Markets. 2018;38:1024–1042.
Received: 17 October 2017
|
Accepted: 17 March 2018
DOI: 10.1002/fut.21921
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Is stock return predictability of option-implied skewness
affected by the market state?
Tong Suk Kim
|
Heewoo Park
College of Business, Korea Advanced
Institute of Science and Technology
(KAIST), Seoul, Republic of Korea
Correspondence
Heewoo Park, College of Business, Korea
Advanced Institute of Science and
Technology (KAIST), 85 Hoegi-ro,
Dongdaemun-gu, Seoul, Republic of Korea.
Email: laax@kaist.ac.kr
We use (Bakshi, Kapadia, and Madan, 2003, Review of Financial Studies 16:
101143) methodology to measure the option-implied ex ante skewness of the risk-
neutral returns distribution for underlying stocks.We find a negative relation between
option-implied skewness and subsequent stock returns, even after controlling for a
myriad of firm-characteristic variables. Specifically, the cross-sectional stock return
predictability of option-implied skewness is only significant during periods of low
market return and high investor sentiment. Furthermore, we find that the predictive
power of skewnesscan be attributed to market state rather than sentiment.Our findings
suggest that investors should consider high option-implied skewness stocks as they
would lottery-like stocks.
KEYWORDS
cross-sectional return predictability, option-implied skewness, skewness preference
JEL CLASSIFICATION
G11, G12, G14
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Over half a century of finance literature has focused on investigating whether investors consider return skewness when they
invest. Arditti (1967) and Scott and Horvath (1980) show that under general assumptions, investors prefer a positive skewness in
returns distribution. Because skewness is largely affected by the outliers of returns, measuring skewness is not a simple task.
Researchers have examined several methodologies to compute skewness, including co-skewness, idiosyncratic skewness, and an
ex ante version of skewness.
1
Recent research has attempted to measure ex ante skewness to investigate the pricing implications of skewness. Boyer,
Mitton, and Vorkink (2009) construct a cross-sectional model of expected idiosyncratic skewness and show that stocks with high
expected idiosyncratic skewness have lower subsequent returns. However, because expected idiosyncratic skewness requires
5 years of data to measure, capturing short-term changes in expected skewness is difficult.
2
Using option data, it is possible to
1
Harvey and Siddique (2000) and Dittmar (2002) provide empirical results that stock returnsco-skewness with the market portfolio return is priced.
Mitton and Vorkink (2007) and Barberis and Huang (2008) establish their models and show that stocks with high idiosyncratic skewness exhibit lower
expected returns.
2
Boyer et al. (2009) denote that expected skewness premium has time-series variation, but they do not find which factors affect the skewness premium.
We refer short-term to one month in this article.
1025
KIM AND PARK
compute ex ante skewness without requiring a long history of data.
3
Option-implied risk-neutral skewness may even capture
short-term changes in the stock return predictability of skewness.
4
To our knowledge, researchers have not examined the time-
varying return-predictive power of option-implied skewness. According to our findings, we can further understand the
characteristics of option-implied skewness.
In this paper, we examine whether the stock return predictive power of option-implied skewness varies with market state and
investor sentiment. Option-implied skewness has a negative relation between subsequent stock returns. First, we find that the
return predictive power of skewness remains even after controlling for firm-characteristic variables that are known to forecast
stock returns such as idiosyncratic volatility, return reversal, momentum, market capitalization, book-to-market ratio, market
beta, and the illiquidity measure. In addition, return predictability of skewness is only significant during downturn market
periods and high investor sentiment states. Kumar (2009) and Fong and Toh (2014) also find that investorsdemand for lottery-
like stocks increases during economic downturns or high investor sentiment periods. Thus, we conclude that investors regard
high option-implied skewness stocks as they do lottery-like stocks. Our analysis suggests that option-implied skewness also has
economic meanings beyond just that of a theoretically calculated measure.
We begin our analysis with daily option data to compute option-implied skewness. There are some advantages using
option-implied skewness to see short-term changes in stock return predictability. First, use of option prices reduces the
need for long time-series stock data to estimate the skewness of a returns distribution. In particular, option-implied
skewness readily captures changes in the return predictive power of skewness during periods of change in the expectation
of investorsskewness preferences. Second, option prices are a market-based estimate of investorsexpectations. Bates
(1991), Rubinstein (1994), and Jackwerth and Rubinstein (1996) find that option prices contain information regarding
market participants. Thus, under the assumption that no-arbitrage rules hold between the options and the stocks market,
option prices contain information identical to stock prices.
5
Third, options contain ex ante expectations of the stock
returns distribution. The predictive power of option data on stock returns is caused by informed traders who choose the
option market to trade first, and then trade in the stock markets (e.g., Chowdhry & Nanda [1991] and Easley, O'hara, &
Srinivas [1998]).
6
We examine whether the return predictability of skewness depends on the market state or not. Kumar (2009) shows that
excess buysell imbalance (EBSI) for high skewness stocks is high when the market return is low. In other words, investors
especially prefer high skewness stocks during bad market states because investors have a similar preference for high skewness
stocks and state lotteries.
7
We separately investigate the return predictability of skewness during downturn markets and upturn
markets. Our results confirm that the return predictability of skewness is only significant during downturn markets.
The return predictability of skewness also depends on the sentiment of market participants. We proxy investor sentiment
index for the University of Michigan consumer sentiment index (MCSI) following Lemmon and Portniaguina (2006). Fisher and
Statman (2003) find a positive correlation between investor sentiment and consumer sentiment. We find that high skewness
stocks exhibit significantly lower subsequent returns during high investor sentiment periods (i.e., levels of the MCSI above the
median value). When investor sentiment is high, investors are more optimistic about the future payoffs of high skewness stocks
and so future returns on such stocks become low. Fong and Toh (2014) also argue that lottery-like stocks exhibit low subsequent
returns only during high investor sentiment periods.
8
In addition, we compare the effect of market returns and the MCSI to the return predictive power of skewness. We examine
the return predictability of skewness in four sample periods that are divided by a two-way classification of market state and
investor sentiment. We find that the return predictability of skewness is mostly affected by market return rather than investor
sentiment. Then we analyze the time-series relations between them. Prior literature finds that consumer sentiment is related to
3
Bakshi and Madan (2000) and Bakshi et al. (2003) show that risk-neutral skewness of stock returns can be calculated by using a set of daily option prices
with different strike prices on that stock. Using Bakshi et al. (2003) risk-neutral skewness, Dennis and Mayhew (2002) and Conrad et al. (2013) examine
cross-sectional stock return predictability of skewness.
4
We calculate option implied skewness using the methodology of Bakshi et al. (2003).
5
Ofek and Richardson (2003) and Battalio and Schultz (2006) say that option prices and the prices of underlying stocks did not diverge during the Internet
bubble when eliminating options of stale price quotes. In section 2.1, we employ filters to avoid misleading prices of options.
6
Bali and Hovakimian (2009), Cremers and Weinbaum (2010), and Xing, Zhang, and Zhao (2010) also use a cross section of options data to show that
option prices include predictive information about stock returns.
7
Lottery studies explain that people find the tiny probability of a large payoff more attractive during bad economic conditions. Mikesell (1994) empirically
shows that people are attracted more toward state lotteries during economic downturns.
8
They define the lottery-like stocks as high MAX stocks. MAX is defined as maximum daily returns (MAX) over the past month.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT