Is a pure TIPS strategy truly risk free?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2015.09.003
Date01 January 2016
Published date01 January 2016
AuthorPaul J. Haensly
Is a pure TIPS strategy truly risk free?
Paul J. Haensly
Collegeof Business and Engineering,The University of Texas of the PermianBasin, 4901 E. University Blvd.,Odessa, TX 79762, USA
abstractarticle info
Articlehistory:
Received17 June 2014
Receivedin revised form 8 March 2015
Accepted24 September 2015
Availableonline 3 October 2015
JEL classication:
G2
Keywords:
Ination-indexed bonds
TIPS
Shortfallrisk
Portfoliomanagement
Ination
ATreasuryInation-ProtectedSecurity (TIPS) is virtuallyrisk free. As an obligationof the U.S. Treasury,it is most-
lyfree of default risk. As an ination-indexedsecurityheld to maturity,it is risk free in terms of purchasingpower.
However,investing in a TIPS-onlyportfoliofor retirement is not riskfree. This paper presentsthe results ofa sim-
ulationanalysis designed toevaluate the performanceof a portfolio of ination-indexed Treasurycoupon bonds.
This study demonstrates that signicant shortfall risk exists for TIPS-only portfolios across a range of savings
plans and thesecurities selection rules.
© 2015 ElsevierInc. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
A portfolio of TreasuryInation Protected Securities(TIPS) appears
to be an ideal candidate for achievinga target level of real consumption
in retirement.TIPS have virtuallyno default risk and are indexedfor in-
ation.By comparison, stocksexpose investorsto considerable risk,and
even conventionalTreasury bonds held to maturityhave ination risk.
For thesereasons, ProfessorZvi Bodie argues thatmost investors should
invest most if not all of their retirementsavings in Treasury ination-
indexed bonds (e.g.Bodie & Clow es, 2003, Chevreau, 2009a, 2009b,
Light, 2009).
This paperevaluates the shortfallrisk of TIPS-onlyportfolios heldfor
retirement.Consider a household earning an incomeat the median for
U.S. households in 2012. Suppos e that their objective is to maintain
the corresponding level of re al income in retirement. This pa per
shows that, across a range of savin gs plans and security selection
rules, the probability is signicant that this householdwill not accumu-
late sufcientwealth in a TIPS-only portfolioto achieve its goal.
The mostobvious reason is thatTIPS offer relativelylow real returns.
An investor could boost the levelof savings in the TIPS-only portfolio.
But this paperdemonstrates that an investorwould need to save prodi-
giouslyin order to reduce shortfallrisk to minimal levels. Anothersolu-
tion is to delay retirement. But th e reduction in the probability of a
shortfallgenerally comes at a signicantcost in the form of lowerutility
of consumption in retirement as well as loss of leisure time (i.e., less
time in retirement). Social Security benets reduce shortfall risk, but
an investor who savesfor retirement in a TIPS-only portfoliostill must
contributeat high levels in order to minimize thisrisk.
Low real returns are not the only factor. Uncertainty about future
real yields creates uncertainty in how much real savings are required
to meet the investor's objectives. The analysis in this paper takes this
factor into account by simulating uncertain real yieldsover time. This
paper also examinesthe effects on shortfall risk of market friction and
risk of involuntary, early permanentretirement (e.g., due to disability).
In addition, not all TIPS selection str ategies perform the same. This
paper shows that the choice of security selection rules can have a signif-
icant effecton shortfall risk.
2. Material andmethods
2.1. Simulatedinvestors
This paper evaluates investment performance in terms of shortfall
risk.This approach isconsistent with Bodieand Clowes (2003),whojus-
tify anall-TIPS portfolio on thegrounds that it minimizesthe risk of fall-
ing short of one'sretirement goals. Supposethat investors are savingto
buy an ination-indexed annui ty at retirement. Shortfall risk can be
measured as P{ω:C
t(S;ω)
(S;ω)bχ}, where Sis a strategy in the invest-
ment strategy space, Θ;ωis a simulated histo ry for one investor;
t(S;w) is the actualdate of retirement; C
τ
(S;w)istheination-indexed
monthly consumption supported by an immediate ination-indexe d
annuity purchased at time τ,givenstrategySfollowed by the investor;
Reviewof Financial Economics28 (2016) 120
Tel.: +1 432 552 7887.
E-mailaddress: haensly_p@utpb.edu.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rfe.2015.09.003
1058-3300/©2015 Elsevier Inc. All rightsreserved.
Contents listsavailable at ScienceDirect
Review of Financial Economics
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rfe
and χis the minimumacceptable levelof real monthly consumptionin
retirement.Equivalently,we can reformulatethis probabilityin terms of
actual pre-tax real retirement incomeversus an income target. In this
paper,the latter interpretation generallyis more convenientfor the pur-
pose of comparingretirement outcomes withthe level of monthly sav-
ings beforeretirement.
For consistency when comparing simulatedinvestor histories, real
values arein terms of purchasing powerat the investor's 25thbirthday,
regardlessof when the investorstarts and stopssaving. Hence, through-
out this paper, theterm real valuerefers to the investor's purchasing
power at age 25 unlessI specify otherwise.
This paperaddresses a claim about shortfallrisk of TIPS-only portfo-
lios.However, expectedutility of each strategyis reported as an alterna-
tive measure of the relative benets when comparing two strate gies
with different shortfall risk. Results are for a time separable utility of
consumption in retirement, whe re the utility function is the natural
log of consumption. Expected utility at retirement is discounted back
to theinvestor's 25th birthdayin all cases (using the sametime discount
factor applied to calculate the expected utility) for consistency when
comparing investors withdifferent retirement dates. In order to focus
on standard of living in retirement, b equests have no utility in the
analysis.
For convenience in the analysis,I replace monthlyreal after-tax con-
sumption in retirementwith monthly real pre-tax retirement income.
Thisincome may arise solelyfrom a TIPS-onlyretirement portfolioliqui-
dated to purchase an ination-indexed annuity, or it may also include
other ination-indexed retirement income such as Social Security ben-
ets. With the natural log of utility and th e size of payments in this
study,the effect of shifting fromafter-tax consumptionto before-tax in-
come on utility is small. For example,if monthly pre-tax annuity pay-
ments are $4000 and the effective average tax rate is 10%, then the
ratio of the log of consumptionto the log of annuity payment is 0.987.
Moreover, the effectis proportional and thus does not change relative
ordering of expected utilities. Hen ce, an analysis of shortfall risk in
terms of pre-tax retirement inc ome at the median household leve l
willlead to approximatelythe same conclusionsin this paperas an anal-
ysis in terms of after-tax consumption.
A simulated investor adopts a lifetim e investment strategy that
consists of a savings plan and a securitiesselection rule. A savings plan
eitherconsists of constantmonthly real dollar contributions or monthly
real dollar contributions that gr ow at a constant rate. Each month
duringthe accumulation phase,the investor pools the newcontribution
withcash owsfromcouponpaymentsandparfrommaturingTIPSand
attempts to invest in TIPS that satisfy the securityselection rule. In all
cases, the investor buys an in ation-indexed immediate ann uity at
retirement.
Each investment strategy isevaluated under three scenarios: (a) no
secondary market frictionand no risk of involuntary early retirement;
(b) secondary market friction and no risk of involuntary early retire-
ment;and (c) secondarymarket friction andrisk of involuntaryearly re-
tirement. When the simulated investor is at risk of involuntary early
retirement, therisk begins at age 52. This risk is based on theNational
Institute on Agingsurvey data reported by Hodes and Suzman (2007).
The probability of involuntary retire ment in each month after the
investor's52nd birthdayis determined bya quadratic modelttoannu-
al data from Figure 2-2, Retirement Pattern for Career Workersin the
First HRS Cohort: 19922002.Although this data includes retirement
for all reasons, health was the primary f actor in early retirement for
more than half of all men and more than one thi rd of all women in
the survey. Achieving sufcien t nancial wealth does not appear to
have been a signicant factor in the reported retirement rates,because
morethan one third of respondentssaid that theyhad saved nothing for
retirement,and three-fourthssaid that they had not savedenough. The
survey data is for retirement in the age range 5 2 to 70 years; in the
simulation, the probability of in voluntary early retirement aft er the
70th birthdayis assumed to be the same as the rate at age 70.
To determinethe monthly ination-indexed annuitypayment that a
given level of wealth can buy, the simulator calculates the immediate
pension annuity factor, assuming disc rete, real monthly payouts
conditionalon the investor's age at retirement. (Pleasesee Appendix A
for details.) To determine the re al payout, the simulator divides the
investor'swealth by the immediatepension annuity factor.The follow-
ing simplifyingassumptions apply to all cases.
The investor saves in a tax-deferre d retirement account, and the
annuity at retirement is held in this account. Th is assumption is
consistentwith the growing roleof tax-deferred denedcontribution
plans in the UnitedStates.
The investor has an accumula tion phase before retirement and a
payout phase after retirement.The investor has earned income only
during the accumulation phase. This assumption is reasonable,
because earnedincome typically falls sharplyat retirement.
The investoruses all wealthin the retirement accountto purchase the
annuity at retirement. Henc e, strategies only concern in vestment
decisionsin the accumulation phase.
The annuityis indexed with no lag to the ConsumerPrice Index for All
Urban Consumers,non-seasonally adjusted (CPI-U).The annuity has
no risk of default and no insurance featu res. Also, assume that the
CPI-U tracksthe investor's personal purchasing power in retirement.
The annuityis the investor's only sourceof income in retirement with
one exception.Dened benet pensionsand income from working in
retirement are notconsidered in this analysis. To the extentthat an-
other source of ination-indexed incom e is available, the investor
could lower the target real consumption that must be supported by
the retirementaccount. Due to the importanceof Social Security ben-
ets tomany retirees, I evaluatethe effect on shortfallrisk if ination-
indexed SocialSecurity payments are available.
Probability of death is modeled as a random event c onsistent with the
mortality rates in the Society of Actuaries (2014). Mortality rates in
this simulation are unisexrates for the total U.S.population calculated
as a simple average of the Societyof Actuaries (SOA) mortality rates
for men and women.I splice the SOA series for juveniles, employees,
and healthy annuitants.
Calculationof shortfall risk isbased on real annuity paymentsexpect-
ed at time of retirement.
2.2. Target savings
In the simulation, I set the target realdollar, pre-tax retirementac-
count payout equal to $51,915 per year or, equivalently,$4326.25 per
month. This value is the median pre-tax annual income among U.S.
households in 2012 (Noss, 2014). Throughout this paper, median pre-
tax family incomerefers to this dollar amount which also is dened to
be in age 25 dollars from the perspective of the simulated investor.
A pair of important relatedquestions arises concerning therealism
of this target.What, in fact, is the retirementincome target for a family
retiring with a medianincome; and does a retired household needthe
same real incomein retirement as beforeretirement?
Interpolating from survey data reported by the Employee BenetRe-
search Institute (Fig. 27 in Helman, Adams, Copeland, & VanDerhei,
2014), the median amount of savings that workers in 2012 thought
they need for retirement was $368,056. Assuming a continuously
compoundedannual real rate of returnof 3% and retirement at age 65,
the correspondingannual real annuity would be $24,657. For the sake
of argument, assume also that this value is the target for workers earning
the median family income just prior to retirement. Although Helman et al.
do not report whether respondents considered Social Security benets to
count as savings, it is reasonable to assume that the respondents excluded
those benets when asked about anticipated savings needed.
Expected Social Security benets co uld range widely. Consider a
worker who began earning the minimum wa ge in 1973 at age 25
2P.J. Haensly/ Review of FinancialEconomics 28 (2016) 120

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT