Investment Financing of Organizational Capital

AuthorDaniel X. Jiang,Miao Luo,Jun Cai
Date01 June 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ajfs.12132
Published date01 June 2016
Investment Financing of Organizational
Capital*
Daniel X. Jiang
Smeal College of Business, The Pennsylvania State University
Miao Luo**
Sun Yat-Sen Business School, Sun Yat-Sen University
Jun Cai
College of Business, City University of Hong Kong
Received 11 January 2016; Accepted 12 February 2016
Abstract
We identify that the cost of external capital and the frontier technology (FT) shock level are
two important factors affecting external capital supply. We explore how they interact to affect
the investment financing of organizational capital (OC). We show that the FT shock level has
experienced a dramatic change from being counter-cyclical before 1991 to pro-cyclical after
1991. This structural break alters the OC investment sensitivities during the two sub-periods.
We find that the OC investment-cash flow sensitivity is low and the OC investment-qsensi-
tivity is high only when the cost of external capital is low and the FT shock level is simulta-
neously high. These patterns are mainly driven by financially constrained firms. In addition,
our empirical findings suggest that OC investments made during recessions when the FT
shock level is also low generate higher productivity than in other conditions.
Keywords Organizational capital; Investment-cash flow sensitivity; Investment-qsensitivity;
Financial constraints; Frontier technology; Business cycle
JEL Classification: E32, G31, G32
*The authors would like to thank the editor (Professor Hee-Joon Ahn), the associate editor,
two anonymous referees, seminar participants at Shanghai Jiaotong University and the Chi-
nese Academy of Sciences for their helpful suggestions and comments. City University of
Hong Kong Strategic Grant (SRG 7008142) is also gratefully acknowledged. All errors remain
our own responsibilities.
**
Corresponding author: Miao Luo, Department of Finance and Investment, Sun Yat-Sen
Business School, Sun Yat-Sen University, 135 West Xingang Road, Guangzhou 510275,
China. Tel: +86-20-8411-1450, Fax: +86-20-8403-6924, email: luomiao.work@gmail.com.
Asia-Pacific Journal of Financial Studies (2016) 45, 343–379 doi:10.1111/ajfs.12132
©2016 Korean Securities Association 343
1. Introduction
Organizational capital (OC) refers to the stock of knowledge or “know-how” firms
accumulate over time (Atkeson and Kehoe, 2005). It measures the knowledge used
to combine human skills and physical capital into a system for producing and deliv-
ering products (Evenson and Westphal, 1995). Compared with physical or human
capital, OC is a unique factor which is capable of yielding abnormal or above cost
of capital returns, thereby generating enterprise growth (Lev and Radhakrishnan,
2005). This distinguishing feature reveals the importance of having a good under-
standing of this intangible capital.
Recent works on this issue have concentrated on the measurement of OC and
its effect on the firm production process (Prescott and Visscher, 1980; Ichniowski
et al., 1997; Hall, 2000; Atkeson and Kehoe, 2005; Lev and Radhakrishnan, 2005;
Lustig et al., 2011; Carlin et al., 2012; Eisfeldt and Papanikolaou, 2012).
1
However,
the literature is silent on financing for OC investment. In this article, we aim to
examine two issues. First, we wish to understand the funding for OC investment
at the firm level. Following the accounting literature (Lev and Radhakrishnan,
2005), we recursively construct the stock of OC by accumulating the value of sell-
ing, general, and administrative expenditures (XSGA), and use XSGA scaled by
OC stock as a measure of OC investment. We will examine the relation between
OC investment and internal and external funding sources by estimating a panel
regression model in which we control for the investment opportunity measured
by Tobin’s Q. OC investment should be positively correlated with both internal
and external funding sources and investment opportunities. Second, we will exam-
ine whether the funding of OC investment varies with business cycles and the
frontier technology (FT) shock initially phrased in Atkeson and Kehoe (2005).
The existing literature suggests that the most important factor in determining the
level of various investments such as fixed asset investment or research and devel-
opment (R&D) investment is the cost of external capital. During economic expan-
sion, the cost of external capital is low; therefore, the investment-cash flow
sensitivity will be lower and the investment-qsensitivity will be higher. Specific to
OC, a positive FT is affiliated with the departure or loss of firm-specific talent
that adversely affects the performance of firm profitability and stock price. There-
fore, the FT shock level is likely to be another important factor influencing OC
investment behavior (Eisfeldt and Papanikolaou, 2012). External shareholders are
more willing to invest in OC when the FT shock level is high. To proxy for the
FT shock level, we construct a hedge portfolio return sorted on the ratio of OC
stock to book assets, or the intensity of OC. A high value of FT indicates more
skilled people leaving their jobs on a market-wide basis as new FT emerges and
1
A number of papers examine the quality of firms’ organizational structure and management
practices using survey data (Caroli and Van Reenen, 2001; Bresnahan et al., 2002; Bloom and
Van Reenen, 2007).
D. X. Jiang et al.
344 ©2016 Korean Securities Association
skilled people exercise their outside option. We will explore how the effects of the
cost of external capital and the FT shock level interact with each other to affect
the investment financing of OC.
We begin our analysis by first examining the cyclical behavior of FT shock and
find that it changes dramatically during our sample period (1971 to 2011). The cor-
relation between the cyclical component of the log of real GDP and our proxy for
FT shock is 0.70 during the 19711990 period and 0.62 during the 19912011
period. In the first half of our sample period prior to 1991, the FT shock level is
counter-cyclical. More skilled people leave jobs in recessions to find better opportu-
nities. This is consistent with the observation that recessions cause a sharp move
toward reorganization. Workers reorganize or find better job matches when the rel-
ative reward to work declines temporarily during recessions (Hall, 2000). This is
also consistent with the fact that the job-finding rate is about the same whether
unemployment is high or low (Blanchard and Diamond, 1990; Hall, 1991). Unem-
ployment that occurs in recessions is concentrated among a small number of firms
making large cutbacks. For the majority of the firms, employment growth occurs at
normal rates (Davis and Haltiwanger, 1990). However, in the second period after
1991, the FT shock level is pro-cyclical. More skilled people leave jobs during times
of expansion. This key talent actively seeks outside options as firms spend more on
information technology when the economy is expanding (Haacker and Morsink,
2001).
2
The structural change is most likely due to the skill-biased technology
change that shifts labor demand toward more highly skilled workers relative to less
skilled workers. The size, breadth, and timing of the recent labor demand shift is
related to the largest and most widespread technology change of the current era,
information technology (Bresnahan et al., 2002). In addition, Bloom et al. (2012)
find that the U.S.A. has experienced a sustained increase in productivity growth
since the mid-1990s, particularly in sectors that intensively use information technol-
ogy. One explanation for this is that U.S. firms are organized in a way that allows
them to use new technologies more efficiently. The break point of 1991 coincides
with the year of productivity paradox in the literature of information technology
spending and financial performance.
3,4
2
Technology shocks and their impact on investment and aggregate spending have become a
main driving force of business cycles (Haacker and Morsink, 2001).
3
The productivity paradox refers to empirical evidence in the 1980s and early 1990s reporting
that there was no statistical association between information technology spending and finan-
cial performance. However, by the mid-1990s, a positive relation had been established (Bryn-
jolfsson and Hitt, 1996; Bharadwaj et al., 1999).
4
Brynjolfsson (1993) proposes that during the pre-1991 period, information technology might
have increased organizational slack, rather than firm productivity and improved financial per-
formance. Two examples of organizational slack are overlay of technology and mismanage-
ment of information technology. Dehning et al. (2004) test the Brynjolfsson (1993)
proposition using selling, general, and administrative expenses.
Investment Financing of Organizational Capital
©2016 Korean Securities Association 345

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT