Inventions and patenting in Africa: Empirical trends from 1970 to 2010

Published date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jwip.12139
AuthorGregory D. Graff,Philip G. Pardey
Date01 March 2020
© 2019 The Authors. The Journal of World Intellectual Property published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd
J World Intellect Prop. 2020;23:4064.40
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/jwip
DOI: 10.1111/jwip.12139
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Inventions and patenting in Africa: Empirical
trends from 1970 to 2010
Gregory D. Graff
1,2,3
|
Philip G. Pardey
3,4
1
Department of Agricultural and Resource
Economics, Colorado State University, Fort
Collins, Colorado
2
Department of Technology Management and
Economics, Chalmers University of
Technology, Gothenburg, Sweden
3
International Science and Technology
Practice and Policy (InSTePP), University of
Minnesota, St. Paul, Minnesota
4
Department of Applied Economics,
University of Minnesota, St. Paul, Minnesota
Correspondence
Gregory D. Graff, Department of Agricultural
and Resource Economics, Colorado State
University, B328 Andrew G. Clark Building,
1200 Center Avenue Mall, Fort Collins,
CO 805231172.
Email: gregory.graff@colostate.edu
Funding information
Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation; U.S.
National Institutes of Health
Abstract
Economic development is increasingly dependent upon on
utilizing new knowledge to innovate and create value, even
in traditional industries and in lowincome countries. This
analysis uses evidence on patent families to assess innova-
tion activity throughout subSaharan Africa. We find patent
activity in subSaharan Africaboth by African inventors
and by foreign inventorsis comparable to similar regions
around the world, when conditioned on economic size.
Patent filings in Africa have grown, particularly, since the
mid1990s, but at different rates within different African
jurisdictions. Types of technologies being patented in Africa
have remained stable over 30 years, with most in pharma-
ceuticals, chemistry, biotechnology, and engineering. The
majority of patent filings in Africa are from Europe, the
United States, and other high income countries. Yet, in South
Africa, between 15% and 20% of patent filings are by
residents of South Africa, and 3% are from other developing
and emerging economies. Only a small share of inventions
globally are made in subSaharan Africa, but for those
inventions that do arise in Africa, foreign filings are made
widely outside of Africa.
KEYWORDS
Africa, intellectual property rights, international technology trans-
fer, patent families, patent offices
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distribution and
reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The worlds first patent statuteadopted in the citystate of Venice in 1474was an early preindustrial economic
development policy. By contrast, the globalized patent system of today may seem far removed from the economic
development goals of lowand middleincome countries, such as those of subSaharan Africa (hereafter,
interchangeably as Africa). This is due, in large part, to the increasing asymmetry in technological capabilities that
have grown, since the Industrial Revolution, between inventors in leading industrialized countries and technological
followers in all other countries. Yet, economic development is increasingly a question of utilizing knowledge to
innovate, solve problems, and create value, even in traditional industries and even in leastdeveloped countries.
This is evidenced by the contributions of new knowledgein the form of vaccines, improved crop varieties, or
mobile telephone and data servicesto the livelihoods of millions. Innovation has played an important role in
meeting several of the Millennium Development Goals, and the need for further innovation is integral to the
framing of the Sustainable Development Goals (United Nations, 2017).
Scholars and policymakers are divided on the role of patents in economic development policy (Barton et al.,
2002; Maskus, 2000; Siebeck, Evenson, Lesser, & Primo Braga, 1990). The negotiation, adoption, and
implementation of common minimum standards under the Trade Related Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)
agreement as part of the World Trade Organization (WTO) Treaty provided ample context for this debate over the
past three decades (Blakeney & Mengistie, 2011; Diwan & Rodrik, 1991), yet it is a debate that has run for far
longer (May & Sell, 2006).
Some argue that intellectual property rights (IPRs) in developing countries are counterproductive to economic
development. The first and strongest argument in this vein is based on the observation that, since more applications
come from inventors in highincome countries, a developing countrys patent system is most likely to issue patent
rights to foreigners. Therefore, a stronger patent system serves mainly to transfer wealth from domestic consumers
to inventors in highincome countries (Maskus, 2000).
The second argument against patents is related to the first, but focuses on domestic producers, holding that
stronger patent regimes in developing countries create difficult conditions for domestic industry to compete
against global technological leaders. Under a weaker patent regime, developingcountry firms have greater freedom
to imitate technologies invented in wealthier countries. The developingcountry imitators can then move, at lower
cost, through the crucial phases of catching up to the global technological frontier. Once they have caught up, it is
conceded, IPRs can then be accordingly strengthened. This pattern, it is argued, has been followed repeatedly in
history, first by firms in Germany and the United States catching up to those in Britain and France in 19th century,
and successively by firms in Japan, Korea, and most recently in China catching up to those in the West.
A third major argument against patents in developing countries has focused on humanitarian issues of access to
technologies that meet fundamental human needs, such as food security and essential medicines (Gold & Lam,
2003; Kapczynski, Chaifetz, Katz, & Benkler, 2005; Orsi, Camara, & Coriat, 2006). Stronger patent regimes in
developing countries, it is argued, tend to increase prices of food and medicines, particularly for the poorest of
consumers for whom these categories make up a large share of typical household budgets. Furthermore, agriculture
and healthcare represent some of the most widespread forms of economic activity in developing countries: with
large segments of the population deriving their livelihoods from smallholder agriculture and with malnutrition,
poverty, and infectious disease creating disproportionate public health and economic burdens. In subSaharan
Africa, such conditions certainly are observed, and, for example, high profile objections erupted in South Africa in
the late 1990s regarding patents on antiretroviral human immunodeficiency virus drugs (Fisher & Rigamonti, 2005;
Ostergard, 1999).
Other scholars caution, however, that developingcountry policymakers should not tooreadily neglect patent
systems, given the increasingly important role that knowledge plays in economic growth. Foremost, it is countered,
under a weak patent system domestic industry, entrepreneurs, or publicly funded researchers choose not to invest
resources in innovative effort, given the lack of incentives from the lack of domestic protections
GRAFF AND PARDEY
|
41

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT