International Coercion and the Diffusion of Regulatory Data Protection

AuthorGabriel J. Michael
Published date01 March 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jwip.12051
Date01 March 2016
International Coercion and the Diffusion of
Regulatory Data Protection
Gabriel J. Michael
Information Society Project, Yale Law School
Prior to 1990, regulatory da ta protection existed onl y in 14 highly developed count ries. Since then, 60 addition al
countries have adopted reg ulatory data protection. New a dopters include a large number of countries with no
domestic pharmaceutical in dustry. These countries wil l face higher pharmaceutical prices as a result of offering
regulatory data protectio n. Why would countries that stand to lose from of fering regulatory data protection choose
to do so? The author argues that the global diffusion of re gulatory data protection can b e directly traced to
international coercion from the United States and the Eur opean Union (EU). The US coerces wea ker trading
partners into adopting regu latory data protection by requi ring such protection as a condit ion of concluding trade
agreements or bilateral int ellectual property agreements. Meanwhile, th e EU coerces applicants by demanding that
they adopt such rights during EU acce ssion negotiations, on average four years prior to accession. H et ested these
claims using a multi-method research design that combines event history an alysis with evidence from lea ked US
diplomatic cables and public EU accession documents. His ndings demonstr ate that coercive diffusion ca n take
place by means of threats, and th at countries often actively opp ose adopting intellectual pr operty rights, but
nevertheless adopt them du e to international coercion.
Keywords TRIPS; bilateralism; pharmaceuticals; intellectual property
Over the past two decades, scores of countries around the world have adopted new and unusual intellectual
property rights. Separate from the traditional areas of copyright, patent and trademark, new sui generis
rights protect exotic subject matter, such as databases, plant varieties or the layout of integrated circuits.
Often the countries adopting these new protections have no clear reason to do so. They have no domestic
industries that stand to benet from new protections, and domestic policymakers often oppose their
introduction. This is especially true of the intellectual property rights protecting the clinical trial data that
pharmaceutical rms submit to regulatory authorities (hereafter regulatory data protection). These data
document the safety and efcacy of pharmaceutical products. Adopting intellectual property rights that
restrict access to these data allows pharmaceutical rms to delay competition from generic manufacturers,
increasing the price of medicine and further burdening public health systems throughout the world.
Prior to 1990, regulatory data protection existed only in 14 highly developed countries. Since then, 60
additional countries have adopted regulatory data protection. The large number of countries adopting this
new intellectual property right poses a puzzle. The new adopters include a large number of countries with
no domestic pharmaceutical industry whatsoever, and these countries will face higher pharmaceutical
prices as a result of offering regulatory data protection. Why would countries that stand to lose from
offering regulatory data protection choose to do so?
This article argues that the global diffusion of regulatory data protection can be directly traced to
international coercion from the United States and the European Union. Although regulatory data
protection increases pharmaceutical prices and harms public health, it benets large pharmaceutical rms
based in the United States and EU member states (El-Said and El-Said, 2007; Malpani, 2009; Shaffer and
Brenner, 2009). The United States coerces weaker trading partners into adopting regulatory data protection
by requiring such protection as a condition of concluding trade or bilateral intellectual property
2©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
The Journal of World Intellectual Property (2016) Vol. 19, no. 1–2, pp. 2–27
doi: 10.1111/jwip.12051
agreements. Meanwhile, the EU coerces applicants by demanding that they adopt such rights during EU
accession negotiations, on average four years prior to accession.
I test these claims using a multi-method research design that combines event history analysis with
detailed evidence gleaned from leaked US diplomatic cables and public EU accession documents. The
statistical analysis nds strong correlations between the decision of a country to sign a trade agreement
with the United States or apply for EU membership and an increased likelihood of adopting regulatory data
protection. These correlations persist even when controlling for a number of key political and economic
variables. Furthermore, I nd no support for explanations of diffusion pointing to the role of international
organizations, learning or mimicry. Leaked diplomatic cables conrm that countries negotiating trade
agreements with the United States actively opposed adopting regulatory data protection but ultimately
caved to US pressure. Likewise, EU accession documents indicate that newly acceding members sought to
delay adopting regulatory data protection as long as possible.
My ndings have signicance for at least two literatures. First, my research demonstrates that coercive
diffusion can take place by means of threats. Powerful states can threaten to withhold or delay promised
benets or remove existing benets, unless a target state adopts a desired policy. This can happen in a
variety of negotiations, such as bilateral trade agreement negotiations, EU accession negotiations, and the
WTO accession process. Over the past few decades, international economic negotiations have experienced
a dramatic shift from the multilateral forum of the GATT/WTO to a plethora of regional, plurilateral and
bilateral agreements (Manseld and Pevehouse, 2013; Menon, 2007). Yet within the diffusion literature,
the focus has been on accounting for the diffusion of the agreements themselves, rather than asking
whether trade agreements and other rapidly proliferating types of agreements might serve as new conduits
for coercion.
1
While the sanctions literature has come to view threats as a frequent and effective form of coercion in
the service of foreign policy goals, the diffusion literature largely focuses on other forms of coercion.
2
These other forms of coercion include conditionality imposed by international nancial institutions and
federal governments; hierarchical coercion imposed by supranational or national governments on lower
governments; soft coercionin the form of go-it-alone power, rst-mover advantages or successful
policies serving as templates for second-comers; and constructivist forms of power exerted through
persuasion, hegemonic ideas or the ability of normative leaders to shape statesbehavior.
3
Some scholars
go so far as to downplay the importance of coercion as a mechanism of diffusion, claiming that coercion is
out of step with our world,(Simmons et al., 2008, pp. 358359). In contrast, my ndings show that
powerful states possess the ability to dictate the terms of law and policy to weaker states by threatening to
withhold benets during various types of negotiations.
Second, the results show that when countries adopt new intellectual property rights like regulatory
data protection, they often do so for reasons other than those commonly suggested by the economic or
international political economy literature. The traditional economic justication for creating intellectual
property rights points to the necessity of such rights to solve market failures that result from the non-rival
and -excludable nature of intangible goods (Landes and Posner, 2003). Countries may also adopt
intellectual property rights in order to benet from their presumed indirect effects, such as fostering
economic development, attracting foreign investment or sending signals about a business-friendly
environment (Braga et al., 2000; Fink and Maskus, 2005; Javorcik, 2004). In contrast to these economic
explanations, my ndings show that countries often actively oppose adopting intellectual property rights,
but nevertheless adopt them due to international coercion. As a result, the so-called harmonization of
intellectual property law does not reect a growing international consensus or the benets of
standardization, but rather the effects of coercion (Duteld and Suthersanen, 2005).
The remainder of the article proceeds as follows: rst, I explain what regulatory data protection is, and
how and why regulatory data came to be protected as intellectual property. I also discuss the negative
International Coercion and Data Protection Gabriel J. Michael
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
The Journal of World Intellectual Property (2016) Vol. 19, no. 1–2 3

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT