INTERNAL CAPITAL MARKETS, FORMS OF INTRAGROUP TRANSFERS, AND DIVIDEND POLICY: EVIDENCE FROM INDIAN CORPORATES

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12135
AuthorP. V. Viswanath,Elena Goldman
Date01 December 2017
Published date01 December 2017
INTERNAL CAPITAL MARKETS, FORMS OF INTRAGROUP TRANSFERS,
AND DIVIDEND POLICY: EVIDENCE FROM INDIAN CORPORATES
Elena Goldman and P. V. Viswanath
Pace University
Abstract
Firms in a business group share ownership structures, allowing them access to sources of
intragroup nancing not available to independent rms. Resources could be transferred
within a group either through intragroup transactions, primarily operational activities
(internal transfers), or through dividends permitting insiders to make investments in
other group rms (external transfers). The rst strategy predicts lower dividends, and the
second predicts the reverse. Using a large data set of listed Indian rms, we look at the
costs of internal transfers versus external transfers and nd that dividend policies of
group rms are better explained by the external transfer hypothesis.
JEL Classification: G32, G34, G35, O16
I. Introduction
Stewart Myers, in his 1984 a rticle, notes an empirical regularity: rms prefer i nternally
generated funds to external na ncing. Myers and Majluf (1985) ex plain this using the
idea that information asymmetry between the rm and capital markets makes external
funds more expensive than int ernal funds. One implication of their theory is that rms
with larger internal capital mar kets would have an advantage beca use they would be
able to obtain funds more easily thr ough internal generation and tra nsmission of funds,
rather than going to the external ca pital markets (ICM hypothesis ). However, it is
difcult to disentangle the ef fect of other variables in the rm, such as growth
opportunities from the operation of internal capital markets within a single rm
(Chahine, Filatotchev, and Pie sse 2007). Business groups, wh ich consist of loosely
related rms linked together by a common, contr olling set of shareholders, pr ovide an
alternative manifestation of such internal capital markets. Ther e is now an established
body of evidence showing that i nternal capital markets of this so rt exist in business
groups. However, there are still many questions that need to be answered about
precisely how such markets work. For one, so me evidence indicates that group
resource movements are used t o enhance efciency; other evi dence suggests that it is
used to transfer wealth from gr oup rms where insiders have low cash ow righ ts to
The authors thank the associate editor for extremely helpful suggestions that contributed greatly to the nal
product. Part of the work on this paper was done while Viswanath was on sabbatical in early 2017 at the
Nabakrushna Choudhury Centre for Developmental Studies (NCDS), Bhubaneshwar, India. He thanks the Centre
for the facilities provided to him during his stay there to enable him to nish this study.
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XL, No. 4 Pages 567610 Winter 2017
567
© 2017 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
other rms, where they have hi gh cash ow rights. For anothe r, resource transfers
could be accomplished eith er internally through the use of operations-related
activities, such as transfer pricing or balance-sheet-related activities, such as
intragroup loans or external ly through the payment of divide nds.
What causes rms to choose between one channel and another? In short, there
are many issues that need to be studied with respect to the operation of group-level
internal capital markets. Our article looks primarily at the second question and examines
the implications for dividend policy. If resources are conserved within the group,
afliated rms would pay lower dividends (internal transfer [IT] hypothesis), whereas in
the alternative scenario (external transfer [ET] hypothesis), dividends would obviously
be higher.
Business groups exist in many Asian countries. These are well known as
keiretsu in Japan and chaebol in Korea; their prevalence in China and India, too, has
been well documented (He et al. 2013). In both Korea and Japan, dividend payouts
are low compared to rms in other countries of similar economic development.
However, it is not clear whether the size of the internal capital market is an important
consideration in the determination of group rmsdividend policies in these
countries. In Japan, usually a banking corporation, called a main bank, is an integral
part of the keiretsu group. As a result, dividend policies are not as important in terms
of obtaining access to capital. In Korea, the state itself promotes chaebols as a
development strategy and uses state-owned banks to direct funds to chaebol
companies. In China, the stock market has not been an efcient mechanism to raise
funds, given that state-owned enterprises (SOEs) form a large proportion of the listed
companies. As a result, access to external capital is limited for most nonstate
enterprises. India, however, is unusual in having both group companies and a
reasonably well-functioning equity capital market. As such, it provides a good
environment to test various aspects of the internal capital markets hypothesis in the
context of dividend policy.
1
As noted above, there is evidence of various kinds of resource transfers among
group rms. For example, Gopalan, Nanda, and Seru (2015) provide evidence that
dividends by group-afliated rms are systematically related to concomitant equity-
nanced investments by other group afliates. Gopalan, Nanda, and Seru (2007) show
that group-afliated rms provide loans to other rms in the same group that are
experiencing nancial distress. Basu and Sen (2015), too, nd that resource movements
out of a group rm are lower if the rm has higher capital needs. Bertrand, Mehta, and
Mullainathan (2002) nd evidence of tunneling. They nd that cash ow shocks are
propagated from the group-afliated rm where they originate to other group-afliated
rms in accordance with cash ow rights of insiders. Manos, Murinde, and Green (2012)
look at differences in dividend policies of group-afliated rms versus stand-alone rms.
1
Gopalan, Nanda, and Seru (2015) look at dividend policies of group rms in a large set of countries, both
developing and developed. However, some of the intragroup data that are available for India are not available for
these other countries; hence, controlling for other theories of dividend policy is still an issue. In any case, they do
not consider the possibility of group rms transferring resources to other group rms through means other than
loans and dividends.
568 The Journal of Financial Research
They nd that group-afliated rms pay higher dividends than stand-alone rms.
2
What
is interesting in looking at all these studies is that there is little evidence of intragroup
ows accomplished through operational activities affecting the income statement. This
is not entirely surprising given that data on transfer pricing and asset sales to group rms
at advantageous prices are, for obvious reasons, not reported. Thus, the only resource
transfers conserving funds within the group that are examined are loans from one group
rm to another rm. Using an expanded data set, Prowessdx, and new measures of
the cost of intragroup funds transfers, we investigate the reasons for a broader category
of resource transfers in group rms. In addition, we look at the impact of group transfers
on group rmsdividend policies and seek to establish whether internal transfers are
more important than external transfers.
3
Bertrand, Mehta, and Mullainathan (2002) and Gopalan, Nanda, and Seru (2007)
do not look at dividend policies, which are the focus of our article. Gopalan, Nanda, and
Seru (2015) do look at dividend policies, as do Basu and Sen (2015). However, Basu and
Sensndings depend strongly on their interpretation of recent changes in sales as
evidence of a rms need for nancial resources; this may be the reason for their inability
to explain why rms retain earnings when their need for funds is low (as measured by
declining sales). Furthermore, they look at competing power structures within a group
and their effect on group rmsdividend policies, whereas we look at the group as a
whole.
4
Our article is perhaps most comparable to Gopalan, Nanda, and Seru (2015).
They show that group rms pay higher dividends and that these dividends are correlated
with equity-nanced contemporaneous and future investments by afliated rms, a
nding that is consistent with the ET hypothesis. Following their specication, we also
include contemporaneous and one-year-ahead aggregate group investments to explain
rm dividend payouts. In addition, we use group capital expenditures for the previous
year. Just as they do, we nd that dividends are higher, the higher are aggregate group
investments. Gopalan, Nanda, and Seru (2015) corroborate their results by looking at the
effect of shocks to the investment opportunity set of a group-afliated rm and nd that
the shock is transmitted to the dividend policies of other group rms. We use a different
approach to obtaining evidence that group rm dividends are paid with the intention of
allowing insiders to transfer resources to other group rms. Specically, we look at the
costs of moving funds internally across group rms and nd that dividend policy is
responsive to the level of these costs. One of the strengths of the Gopalan, Nanda, and
Seru (2015) study is that they use a multicountry data set; however, this restricts their use
of variables that are not available for all of the countries in their data set. We are able,
2
Manos, Murinde, and Green (2012) control only for a few relevant rm-related variables. They include some
variables such as standard deviation of residuals from a market model and noninstitutional shareholder holdings to
measure information asymmetry, but they do not use industry afliation or capital intensity or any measures of
expected rm growth rate.
3
Our article is possibly the rst to investigate dividend policies of group rms to use the new Prowessdx data
set, which has increased the number of rms covered by about 28% according to the Centre for the Monitoring of
the Indian Economy, which publishes data on Indian rms.
4
Basu and Sen (2015) nd that rms retain earnings and pay out less dividends when their sales are declining,
anding that supports neither efciency nor opportunism approaches.
Internal Capital Markets 569

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT