Intermediaries, transport costs and interlinked transactions

Date01 May 2018
Published date01 May 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12375
REGULAR ARTICLE
Intermediaries, transport costs and interlinked
transactions
M
elanie Lef
evre
1
|
Joe Tharakan
1,2
1
HEC-Management School, University of
Liege, Belgium
2
Centre for Operations Research and
Econometrics (CORE), University of
Leuven, Belgium
Correspondence
Joe Tharakan, Place des Orateurs 3,
4000 Li
ege 1, Belgium.
Email: j.tharakan@ulg.ac.be
Abstract
Farmers in developing countries often encounter difficul-
ties selling their products on local markets. Inadequate
transport infrastructure in rural areas and large distances
between areas of production and consumption mean that
farmers find it costly to bring their produce to the market
and this very often results in small net margins and pov-
erty among farmers who are geographically isolated.
Agriculture in developing countries is characterized by
the presence of intermediaries that have a cost advantage
over farmers. Because of their market power, these inter-
mediaries are able to impose interlinked contracts and are
free to choose the spatial pricing policy they use. In this
paper, we develop a model of inputoutput interlinked
contracts between an intermediary and geographically dis-
persed farmers. We establish when the intermediary uses
either uniform or mill pricing policies, as opposed to spa-
tial discriminatory pricing. For each pricing policy, we
analyze what the welfare implications are in terms of an
increase in farmersincome and a reduction in poverty in
rural areas. We also establish how the choice of a spatial
pricing policy impacts geographically isolated farmers
and how it influences the participation by farmers.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Smallholder farming constitutes about 80 percent of African agriculture. Five hundred million of
such farms provide income to about two-thirds of the 3 billion rural people in the world (IFAD,
2013). While a large number of individuals in rural areas in developing countries depend on it,
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12375
484
|
©2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode Rev Dev Econ. 2018;22:484506.
small-scale agriculture has suffered since the 1980s with globalization and agro-industrialization
causing small farms to go out of business (Reardon & Barrett, 2000). Small farmersaccess to land
has been shown to decrease over time (Jayne, Yamano, & Nyoro, 2004). Furthermore, the World
Bank (2007) reports that an estimated 75 percent of poor people in developing countries live in
rural areas. Most of them depend directly or indirectly on agriculture for their livelihoods. In South
Asia and Sub-Saharan Africa, the number of poor people in rural areas is still increasing and is
expected to stay above the number of urban poor, at least until 2040 (World Bank, 2007). The
prevalence of hunger is still greater in rural than in urban areas (Von Braun, Swaminathan, &
Rosegrant, 2004) and rural children are nearly twice as likely to be underweight as urban ones
(World Bank, 2011).
Different reasons explain the decline of small-scale agriculture in developing countries. High
transport costs are one of them. Small-scale farmers face high transport costs to reach local mar-
kets because of inadequate rural transport infrastructures, combined with large distances between
areas of production and areas of consumption. Transport costs also affect farmers negatively
through the cost of access to inputs that reduce both input use and agricultural production (Staal,
Baltenweck, Waithaka, De Wolff, & Njoroge, 2002; Holloway, Nicholson, Delgado, Staal, & Ehui,
2000). Isolated farmers are less productive (Stifel & Minten, 2008; Binswanger, Khandker, &
Rosenzweig, 1993) and have lower incomes (Jacoby, 2000) than farmers who have an easier
access to the market. Small-scale farms are especially affected as they are unable to make the nec-
essary investments to overcome the disadvantage linked to these transport costs.
Evidence suggests that agriculture in developing countries is increasingly characterized by
smallholder farmers producing commodities on contract with agro-industrial firms (International
Fund for Agricultural Development [IFAD], 2003). In Mozambique, 12 percent of the rural popu-
lation is working on a contract basis with local enterprises that are affiliated with international
companies. In Kenya, 85 percent of sugar cane production depends on small-scale farmers who
provide their production to sugar companies. These intermediaries often have some advantage over
farmers. They can, for example, transport goods to the location of consumption at a lower cost
(transporting them in larger quantities with trucks, transforming them to reduce their volume and/
or perishability, etc.), or they can transform the product enabling them to charge a higher price.
Obtaining this advantage often requires incurring an important fixed cost, which farmers cannot
make. Examples of such intermediaries include maize, beans, roots, and tubers in Malawi and
Benin (Fafchamps & Gabre-Madhin, 2006), mandarin in Nepal (Pokhrel & Thapa, 2007), and
cashews in Mozambique (McMillan, Welch, & Rodrik, 2003).
Hence the question is whether contracting with these intermediaries leads to an increase in
farmersincomes. If this is the case, then helping setting up these intermediaries (through, e.g.,
grants or subsidies) would be another way to reduce poverty in rural areas. However, contracts
between intermediaries and farmers involve interlinked transactions. The intermediary not only
buys the agricultural output from the farmer, but also provides him with the input that is necessary
for his production with the price of both goods being simultaneously fixed. The use of these con-
tracts has been documented for various countries and sectors [see for instance Warning and Key
(2002) for the groundnut sector in Senegal; Jayne et al. (2004) for cash crops production in Kenya ;
Simmons, Winters, and Patricks (2005) for various Indonesian sectors; or Key and Runsten (1999)
for the Mexican frozen vegetable industry]. Existing theoretical work, for example, Gangopadhyay
and Sengupta (1987), suggests that because of the use of interlinked contracts farmers would not
benefit from the intermediarieslower costs. They show that these contracts lead to a n efficiency
gain, but also that this gain is completely appropriated by the intermediary. This result depends on
the assumption that the intermediary can set a different contract for each farmer. In a spatial
LEF
EVRE AND THARAKAN
|
485

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT