Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity and Exporting Behaviour

Published date01 July 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12423
AuthorJiangyong Lu,Zhigang Tao,Yi Sun,Yi Lu
Date01 July 2017
Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity and
Exporting Behaviour
Jiangyong Lu
1
,YiLu
2
, Yi Sun
3
and Zhigang Tao
4
1
Peking University, Beijing, China,
2
Department of Economics, National University of Singapore,
Singapore,
3
Shanghai University of International Business and Economics, Shanghai, China and
4
Faculty of Business and Economics, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong
1. INTRODUCTION
THE new new-trade literature has uncovered the importance of firm-level variations, par-
ticularly firm productivity, in determining exporting behaviour. A dominant theoretical
explanation for exporters being generally more productive than non-exporters in this literature
is the assumption of a fixed cost of exporting, under which the more productive firms self-
select to become exporters.
1
What is implicitly assumed in this literature is that firms export
directly by themselves to foreign countries. In reality, however, many firms, especially those
in developing economies, export through intermediaries,
2
which may significantly reduce the
costs of exporting and consequently have radical implications for the predictions of the new
new-trade theory.
Recently, intensive effort has been made to investigate the role of intermediaries. While
much understanding has been gained regarding how intermediaries facilitate trade (e.g. Feen-
stra and Hanson, 2004; Antras and Costinot, 2011) and how they differ from direct exporters
(e.g. Rauch and Watson, 2004; Ahn et al., 2011), a fundamental question remains unan-
swered, that is what types of firms export through intermediaries and what types of firms
export directly by themselves. This paper fills in the gap by offering a theoretical analysis of
exporting behaviour in the presence of export intermediaries and firm heterogeneity. Furt her-
more, this paper, among the first few studies, provides direct evidence on the relation between
firm productivity and methods of exporting.
3
Our theoretical analysis is built upon a standard trade framework: a home country plus N
foreign countries, two sectors (i.e. a homogeneous good and a continuum of differentiated
goods), and one production factor (i.e. labour). Production takes place in the home country,
and firms can directly export to Nforeign countries by incurring a fixed cost (Melitz, 2003).
As in Chaney (2009), we assume that the fixed cost of direct exporting differs acro ss foreign
countries.
Jiangyong Lu acknowledges research supports from the National Science Foundation of China
(#71525004). Yi Lu acknowledges research supports from the National University of Singapore (the
Ministry of Education AcRF Tier 1 FY2014-FRC2-001).
1
For empirical evidence, see Bernard and Jensen (1995, 1999 2004), Bernard and Wagner (1997), Cler-
ides et al. (1998); for theoretical analysis, see Melitz (2003), Bernard et al. (2003).
2
For example, about 80 per cent of Japanese exports and imports in the early 1980s was handled by
300 trade intermediaries (Rossman, 1984). In China, at least 22 and 18 per cent of its exports and
imports, respectively, in 2005 flew through intermediaries (Ahn et al., 2011). In Sweden, about 15 per
cent of export came through intermediaries in 2005 (Akerman, 2010).
3
The two exceptions are (McCann 2013) and (Abel-Koch 2011) which use firm-level data sets from the
Eastern Europe and Turkey, respectively.
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 1381
The World Economy (2017)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12423
The World Economy
The departure of our model from the literature is that firms can also use intermediaries to
export to foreign countries. Intermediaries can facilitate trade by helping firms sear ch for their
trading partners and by alleviating the problem of information asymmetries between the trad-
ing parties (Rubinstein and Wolinsky, 1987; Biglaiser, 1993). In this paper, we focus on how
firms make exporting decisions in the presence of intermediaries, instead of how intermedi-
aries work, which has been studied in the literature (for a survey of this literature, see, e.g.,
Spulber, 1996). Following Rauch and Watson (2004) and Ahn et al. (2011), we assume that
when using intermediaries to export, firms need to share a portion of their exporting revenue
with intermediaries. Meanwhile, based on the findings of Blum et al. (2009), we assume that
when using intermediaries to export, firms do not need to incur the fixed cost of direct export-
ing but a lower fixed cost of dealing with the intermediaries.
4
Under this model set-up, we can show that as a firm’s productivity increases, it switches
from having sales in the home country only to having both sales in the home country and
exporting. Regarding the methods of exporting, as a firm’s productivity increases, it starts
with exporting through intermediaries, then proceeds to both direct exporting and exporting
through intermediaries, and finally, to direct exporting. Moreover, as a firm’s productivity
increases, it starts with exporting to some foreign countries, and finally, to all foreign coun-
tries.
Next, we empirically investigate the relation between firm productivity and exporting beha-
viour. The data come from Private Enterprise Survey of Productivity and the Investment Cli-
mate (PESPIC), which is a standardised data based on a series of The World Bank Enterprise
Surveys (WBESs) conducted by the Enterprise Analysis Unit of the World Bank. There are a
total of 12,679 firms in 29 developing economies during the period of 200206. PESPIC con-
tains unique information about firms’ methods of exporting, including direct exporting,
exporting through intermediaries and both. It is found that 27 per cent of exporters use inter-
mediaries and 11 per cent of exporters export both directly and through intermediaries, which
indicate the importance of intermediaries for exporting.
To uncover what types of firms use which exporting methods, we first compare firms along
six dimensions (i.e. output, employment, capital, output per worker, capital per worker and
total factor productivity). It is found that firms with both sales in the home country and direct
exporting always have the highest mean value, followed by those with sales in the home
country and exporting both directly and through intermediaries, than those with sales in the
home country and exporting through intermediaries, and finally, those with sales in the home
country only. These preliminary results are consistent with our theoretical predictions.
To further establish the relation between firm productivity and methods of exporting, we
conduct a regression analysis. It is found that along with the increase in productivity, a firm
switches from having sales in the home country only to having sales in the home country and
exporting through intermediaries, then to having sales in the home country and exporting both
directly and through intermediaries, and finally to having sales in the home country and direct
exporting. These findings are consistent with our theoretical prediction.
To conclude that our empirical findings are not biased due to some estimation problems,
we conduct a series of robustness checks, such as addressing the endogeneity of firm
4
We also discuss alternative arrangements between exporters and intermediaries, but find that the result-
ing theoretical predictions regarding the relation between firm productivity and methods of exporting are
not supported by the empirical regularities. See the Appendix for details.
©2016 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1382 J. LU ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT