Intergenerational transfers, demographic transition, and altruism: Problems in developing Asia

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12369
Published date01 August 2018
AuthorManachaya Uruyos,Yoshitaka Koda
Date01 August 2018
SPECIAL ISSUE ARTICLE
Intergenerational transfers, demographic transition,
and altruism: Problems in developing Asia
Yoshitaka Koda
|
Manachaya Uruyos
Chulalongkorn University, Bangkok,
Thailand
Correspondence
Yoshitaka Koda, Faculty of Economics,
Chulalongkorn University, 254 Phayathai
Road, Pathumwan, Bangkok 10330,
Thailand.
Email: yoshitaka.k@chula.ac.th
Funding Information
This research was funded by the
Ratchadapisek Sompoch Endowment
Fund (2015), Chulalongkorn University
(CU-58-073-AS).
Abstract
This paper develops a three-period overlapping-genera-
tions model where middle-aged agents care about not
only their own lifetime utility but also their old par-
entsand childrens well-being. The doubly altruistic
agents choose amounts of intergenerational transfers to
their old parents and children as well as private sav-
ings. The government specifies amounts of public trans-
fers from working adults to the dependents. The model
also takes the effects of demographic transition on the
burdens of supporting the elderly and children into
account. Using 23 countriesdata from the National
Transfer Accounts (NTA), we estimate the degrees of
filial and parental altruism and adjust them for their
respective life expectancy and fertility rates. The find-
ings suggest that people in developing countries are
more parentally altruistic than those in developed ones
while the adjusted degree of filial altruism tends to be
low in developing Asia. Our welfare analyses reveal
that the developing Asian countries must introduce
more comprehensive public welfare programs for the
elderly to maximize social welfare. Moreover, their low
adjusted degree of filial altruism may trap the develop-
ing Asian countries at the low levels of public old-age
support and social welfare as the further demographic
transition ensues.
DOI: 10.1111/rode.12369
904
|
©2017 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/rode Rev Dev Econ. 2018;22:904927.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
As an economy develops, increasingly large amounts of resources are transferred from working
adults, who produce more than they consume, to their elder parents and children, who consume
more then they produce. Lee and Mason (2011) illustrate the life-cycle deficit, which is given as
consumption minus labor income, in three different stages of development: huntergatherers, poor
agricultural populations, and rich industrial populations. In all three societies, young parents have a
negative life-cycle deficit. People in both rich and poor countries have positive life-cycle deficits
in their childhood and old adulthood. The life-cycle deficits are larger for children and the elderly
in rich countries owing to their larger expenditures on education, healthcare, and old-age support.
Larger asset income in rich countries also raises their consumption and hence life-cycle deficits.
Though the life-cycle deficit of children in huntergatherer societies is positive, that of the elderly
is negative because they work until the end of life. In summary, Lee and Mason (2011) point out
that the life-cycle deficits of dependent family members have increased sharply with development.
The absence of asset income in huntergatherer societies implies that intergenerational transfers
cover all life-cycle deficits of children. In later stages of development, consumption can be funded
partly by relying on assets. While dependents in poor countries count a great deal on transfers
from working adults to cover their life-cycle deficits, those in rich countries rely more on assets
income.
1
Because of the demographic transition, the burden of sustaining the dependents has been chang-
ing. For young parents, the decreasing number of children eases the burden of sustaining their chil-
drens consumption. An improvement in longevity and a decrease in the number of siblings intensify
the burden of sustaining their old parentsconsumption since each individual is expected to take care
of their elderly parents more. In addition, when the number of children decreases, family old-age sup-
port mechanisms via private transfers have higher default risks owing to nonsurvival or noncompli-
ance of children. As a result, governments in developed nations have instituted various public
welfare programs for the elderly as alternatives to the private old-age support mechanisms (Ehrlich &
Lui, 1998). As it is well known that welfare programs for children increase future productivity of the
economy, the same governments have introduced public transfers to children to make sure that every
child gets proper care and education. If we turn to the political economy literature, Becker and Mur-
phy (1988) point out that investments in childrens education by altruistic parents may be insufficient
because there cannot exist a contract that obliges children to compensate them in the future. The re-
fore, public spending on education packaged with public pensions is needed to achieve the optimal
education level. While these public welfare programs often crowd out private transfers, the govern-
ment interventions do not release young adults from the burden of supporting their d ependents. As
Nishimura and Zhang (1995) suggest, from the perspective of each young agent who makes contribu-
tions to welfare programs, public transfers are viewed as forced private transfers. Therefore, even
after public welfare programs are introduced, ongoing demographic transition makes the total burden
of raising children smaller and that of supporting elderly parents larger.
In this study, we utilize data compiled by the National Transfer Accounts (NTA). The NTA
normalizes an average annual transfer that each of the dependents receives as a percentage of aver-
age labor income of prime-age (3049) adults.
2
In 2004, each child from age 0 to 29 in India,
Thailand, and Japan received normalized transfers equal to 0.26, 0.34, and 0.40 respectively, from
their parents and governments.
3
In the same year, the same young parents and governments pro-
vided each elderly adult from age 60 to 89 with normalized transfers equal to 0.08, 0.21, and 0.42,
respectively. This suggests that both the per capita transfers to children and to the elderly increase
with the level of development, albeit the differences in the latter are more pronounced. Once the
KODA AND URUYOS
|
905

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT