Interest Group Success in the European Union

AuthorDavid Marshall,Patrick Bernhagen,Andreas Dür
DOI10.1177/0010414014565890
Published date01 July 2015
Date01 July 2015
Subject MatterArticles
Comparative Political Studies
2015, Vol. 48(8) 951 –983
© The Author(s) 2015
Reprints and permissions:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
DOI: 10.1177/0010414014565890
cps.sagepub.com
Article
Interest Group Success
in the European Union:
When (and Why) Does
Business Lose?
Andreas Dür1, Patrick Bernhagen2,
and David Marshall3
Abstract
Business lobbying is widespread in the European Union (EU). But because
not all lobbying is successful, the following question arises: When does
business win and when does it lose in the context of legislative policy making
in the EU? We argue that business actors are, overall, less successful than
citizen groups in the European policy process. However, they can protect
their interests if interest group conflict is low or the role of the European
Parliament is restricted. A new data set on the positions of more than 1,000
non-state actors with respect to 70 legislative acts proposed by the European
Commission between 2008 and 2010 allows us to evaluate this argument.
Empirical support for our expectations is highly robust. Our findings have
implications for the literature on legislative decision-making in the EU and
for research on non-state actors in international organizations.
Keywords
business and politics, European Union, interest groups, lobbying success
Business interests’ attempts at influencing public policy are ubiquitous in the
European Union (EU). The EU is sufficiently important to attract lobbying
1University of Salzburg, Austria
2University of Stuttgart, Germany
3University of Aberdeen, UK
Corresponding Author:
Andreas Dür, University of Salzburg, Rudolfskai 42, Salzburg, 5020, Austria.
Email: andreas.duer@sbg.ac.at
565890CPSXXX10.1177/0010414014565890Comparative Political StudiesDür et al.
research-article2015
952 Comparative Political Studies 48(8)
from a large number of business interests: Its institutions legislate on the
terms under which goods and services can be produced and traded in what, if
considered a single unit, is the largest economy in the world. To illustrate, in
late 2012 and early 2013, the EU institutions were the target of a massive
lobbying campaign by Internet companies, including Facebook and Google,
asking for changes to a proposed data protection directive. More than 3,000
proposals for amendments were forwarded to the European Parliament alone.
But lobbying frequently takes place in contested environments, so that not all
lobbyists can expect to be equally successful. Therefore, the question arises:
How successful are business actors in getting what they want? Or, formulated
differently, when and why does business win or lose in the policy struggle?
We argue that, in the EU, business actors are more often than not unsuc-
cessful in achieving their desired policy outcomes. Most legislative proposals
in the EU concern market regulation, which is frequently opposed by a large
majority of business actors. Therefore, business routinely faces a defensive
battle from the moment the European Commission puts forward a proposal
for new legislation. As most Commission proposals eventually lead to legis-
lation, we argue that business frequently loses compared with the status quo
and at best manages to limit the size of its losses. Citizen groups, by contrast,
frequently support new regulation. Once the Commission fields a legislative
proposal, these groups can expect considerable gains compared with the sta-
tus quo. In these situations, business actors may still be able to defend their
interests as long as policy is agreed upon in relatively closed elite circles
involving few interest representatives and executive officials. In the context
of the EU, this is the case when a policy episode is marked by low levels of
controversy or when the role of the European Parliament is limited.
A new data set containing the positions of 1,043 non-state actors on 112
controversial issues included in 70 different legislative proposals introduced
by the European Commission between 2008 and 2010 allows us to assess this
argument.1 We find that on much of EU legislation the Commission, in alli-
ance with citizen groups and the European Parliament, wants to change the
status quo while business interests seek to defend it. The legislative outcomes
tend to shift policy closer to the preferences of citizen groups and further
away from the preferences of business interests. This tendency is amplified
by increased levels of conflict and enhanced institutional powers of the
European Parliament. Our findings are robust to controlling for conflict
among business actors and varying the measurement of success.
Our study is one of the first to systematically assess the success of a large
number of actors across many policy issues for the case of the EU. The two
studies that come closest to our analysis both conclude that group type does
not matter for success (Klüver, 2013; Mahoney, 2008). Contrary to these
Dür et al. 953
studies, we argue that group type is a key variable in explaining interest group
success. Furthermore, we move beyond these earlier studies by arguing that
business success is conditional on the level of conflict. Additional strengths
of our approach include the assessment of success at the level of unidimen-
sional issues, the use of a more fine-grained measure of success, and control-
ling for what would happen in the absence of legislative agreement.
In showing that the success of business actors in EU legislative lobbying
is actually quite limited we shed light on a long-standing debate about the
role of business in EU politics. On one hand, a considerable body of research
suggests that business interests are the most powerful non-state actors in cap-
italist democratic systems (see, for example, McFarland, 1991; Olson, 1965;
Schlozman & Tierney, 1986). This should be no different in the case of the
EU. Indeed, a considerable number of observers suggest that business inter-
ests are more influential than other types of actors in the EU (Dür & De
Bièvre, 2007; Schneider & Baltz, 2003; Streeck & Schmitter, 1991). Business
interests have been portrayed as a major influence on the Single European
Act (Cowles, 1995). They have also been shown to enjoy better access to the
EU than citizen groups (Beyers, 2002; Rasmussen & Carroll, 2014). The
EU’s institutional bias in favor of policies promoting market efficiencies
(Scharpf, 2002) and a regulatory race to the bottom caused by capital market
liberalization in the EU may further facilitate business success.
On the other hand, several studies have pointed out that the EU’s institu-
tional structure allows citizen groups—defined as groups advancing interests
that are not directly related to the vocations or professions of their members
or supporters (Berry, 1999)—to be particularly effective (Geddes, 2000;
Mazey, 1998; Mazey & Richardson, 1993). The EU’s multiple tiers of gov-
ernment provide numerous access points that these diffuse interests can use
to influence decision-makers. The Commission is sympathetic to citizen
groups because they serve as allies in its attempts to enhance its competences
and legitimacy (Pollack, 1997). The growing powers of the European
Parliament, which offers particularly easy access to citizen groups (Kohler-
Koch, 1997), further aids diffuse interests in pursuing their political goals.
Last, the increasing politicization of at least some aspects of EU politics,
which leads to greater public attention to EU policies, may also favor citizen
groups (Dür & Mateo, 2014). Our argument is sympathetic to this second line
of reasoning, but adds important qualifications.
In addition to speaking to the debate about business power in the EU, our
theoretical argument and the operationalization of lobbying success also con-
tribute to the broader literature on interest group success and influence
(Bernhagen, 2012; McKay, 2012; Nelson & Yackee, 2012). Furthermore, our
study is of interest to the wider literature on legislative bargaining in the EU
(e.g., Golub, 2012; Thomson, 2011). In particular, it adds a crucial

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT