Intentions to Return of Clandestine Migrants: Comment

Date01 February 2013
AuthorOded Stark,Lukasz Byra
Published date01 February 2013
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/rode.12023
Intentions to Return of Clandestine Migrants:
Comment
Oded Stark and Lukasz Byra*
Abstract
We take issue with the reasoning of Coniglio et al. (2009) that whereas better-skilled illegal migrants will
prefer to return-migrate, lower-skilled illegal migrants will not. We argue that under asymmetric
information, all the illegal migrants are initially paid a wage based on the average productivity of the group
of illegal migrants.The better-skilled illegal migrants thus face two “taxes:” being paid less than if they were
legal, and being averaged down.Therefore, better-skilled illegal migrants can be expected to expend more
effort to become legal than lower-skilled illegal migrants.And once legalized, there is no reason for the
better-skilled illegal migrants to want to return to their country of origin more than the lower-skilled illegal
migrants.Thus, it is the lower-skilled illegal migrants that are likely to dominate the return migration flow.
We argue that in other respects too, the model of Coniglio et al. is not based on reasonable assumptions,
and that even under the postulated assumptions, the model suffers from several inconsistencies. In
particular, when the rate of return to savings is an increasing function of skill level, we would expect there
to be few better-skilled individuals among illegal migrants in the first place. Also, an obvious distinction
between savers and borrowers is ignored.
1. Introduction
In a recent issue of this Review, Coniglio et al. (2009) sought to explain why
better-skilled illegal migrants will find it optimal to return to their country of origin,
whereas lower-skilled illegal migrants will not. Employing a simple two-period
life-cycle framework with individuals who are heterogeneous with respect to their
skill level, and where illegality causes “skill waste” by reducing a migrant’s rate of
return to skill (a form of taxation on earnings), an illegal migrant faces the following
decision at the end of the first period of his life: to stay put and face a fixed positive
probability of legalization, or to return home. As modeled, the outcome of this
decision hinges crucially on a presumption that not only the individuals’ earnings, but
also the rate of return to the savings that the individuals accumulate during the first
period of their life depend positively on skill level. These savings cannot be put to full
use in the host country because of the migrant’s illegal status, and thus are “taxed” in
a similar way to the migrants’ earnings. Coniglio et al. maintain that better-skilled
illegal migrants find it optimal to return to their home country, where they can use
their savings to undertake an entrepreneurial activity, which in turn provides them
with a higher rate of return to their savings than they would have received had
they remained in the host country. The model appears to constitute an attempt
* Stark (corresponding author): Universities of Bonn, Klagenfurt, and Vienna; Warsaw University;
Warsaw School of Economics. Address for correspondence: Oded Stark, ZEF, University of Bonn,
Walter-Flex-Strasse 3, D-53113 Bonn, Germany. E-mail: ostark@uni-bonn.de. Byra: Faculty of Economic
Sciences, Warsaw University, Dluga Street 44/50, 00-241 Warsaw, Poland. E-mail: lbyra@wne.uw.edu.pl.The
support of Georgetown University Edmund A. Walsh School of Foreign Service in Qatar is gratefully
acknowledged.
Review of Development Economics, 17(1), 156–162, 2013
DOI:10.1111/rode.12023
© 2013 Blackwell Publishing Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT