Intellectual Property Rights, FDI, R&D and Economic Growth: A Cross‐country Empirical Analysis

Published date01 July 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/twec.12304
AuthorWen‐Hsien Liu
Date01 July 2016
Intellectual Property Rights, FDI, R&D
and Economic Growth: A Cross-country
Empirical Analysis
Wen-Hsien Liu
Department of Economics, Institute of International Economics,
National Chung Cheng University, Min-Hsiung, Taiwan
1. INTRODUCTION
ROMER (1990), Grossman and Helpman (1991) and Aghion and Howitt (1992) all
address the importance of technological progress as a key determinant of long-run econ-
omic growth. They believe that technological progress can be attributed to a firm’s profit-
maximisation behaviour in which enormous profits are generated by consistently introducing
new products or improving existing ones. Firms are willing to conduct innovative activities
because they expect to profit from their inventions which are protected by intellectual prop-
erty rights (IPRs). Therefore, economic growth that depends on innovation is likely to be
boosted by IPRs protection. However, there is limited literature that directly tests whether
stronger IPRs protection is likely to result in higher economic growth. Whether strengthening
the IPRs regime can enhance economic growth still needs more comprehensive and persuasive
cross-country empirical evidence.
This paper is intended to fill in this lacuna of the present research by exploring how IPRs,
research and development (R&D) and foreign direct investment (FDI), along with other possi-
ble variables, may affect the economic growth of the host country. Using a longer time series
(38 years) and more cross-sections (92 countries), this paper contributes to the literature by
providing more comprehensive empirical evidence than previous studies on the relationship of
economic growth and its explanatory variables. In addition, this paper uses the newly devel-
oped system generalised method of moments (system GMM) methodology to solve the poten-
tial endogeneity problem. Thus, the results from this paper are believed to be more trustworthy
than previous studies that ignore endogeneity. I finally conclude from the analysis that domes-
tic investment share, FDI, R&D capacity, openness to trade, human capital investment and
IPRs protection all have statistically significant and positive impacts on economic growth for
the full sample of countries. A further investigation of countries at different levels of develop-
ment suggests two major findings. First, besides domestic investment, openness, human capital
and IPRs protection, R&D is the key to drive economic growth in the higher-income countries,
while FDI is the engine of growth in both the higher-income and the middle-income countries.
Second, a positive and statistically significant impact of IPRs protection on economic growth
I would like to thank the editor, David Greenaway, two anonymous referees and conference participants
at the 2009 Symposium on R&D and Innovation (National Taiwan University) for their valuable com-
ments and incisive suggestions which helped to improve the paper substantially. Financial support from
the Ministry of Science and Technology (formerly National Science Council) of Taiwan (grant number:
NSC-96-2415-H-194-007) is also gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 983
The World Economy (2016)
doi: 10.1111/twec.12304
The World Economy
is found in both higher-income and lower-income countries. But for the middle-income coun-
tries, no significant relationship between IPRs protection and growth appears to exist.
The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. Section 2 provides a review of the lit-
erature. Section 3 introduces the data and empirical model used in this paper. The empirical
results are reported and discussed in Section 4, while Section 5 concludes the paper.
2. LITERATURE BACKGROUND
a. R&D, Technological Progress and Economic Growth
In the past two decades, economists have focused on how endogenous technological pro-
gress may influence the patterns of economic growth. In the so-called endogenous R&D-dri-
ven growth models pioneered by Romer (1986), technological progress (usually phased in
terms of growth of total factor productivity, TFP growth) is generated by utilising human cap-
ital and the obtainable knowledge stock. It is then applied to the production process and
results in everlasting increases in the growth rate of output (economic growth). Jones (1995)
first employed the time series trends of TFP growth and the growth rate of the numbers of
scientists and engineers in the United States, Germany, Japan and France to examine the
soundness of the R&D-driven growth model. Yet, he did not find evidence that these variables
are positively linked. For this contradicting result, Aghion and Howitt (1998) provide some
elucidations and argue that in lieu of the number of scientists and engineers, R&D investment
as a percentage of GDP should be used to take into account the country-size effect. Several
subsequent studies present solid evidence that R&D investment is positively related to TFP
growth in the United States (Scherer, 1982; Griliches and Lichtenberg, 1984; Zachariadis,
2003). This positive relationship has also been verified by other studies applying international
data (Frantzen, 2000; Griffith et al., 2004).
b. FDI, Knowledge Diffusion and Economic Growth
The diffusion of knowledge is often considered as a major source of technological progress
and productivity growth. Romer (1986), Lucas (1988, 1993) and Grossman and Helpman
(1991) all ascertain that knowledge diffusion is an important mechanism underlying endoge-
nous economic growth. Meanwhile, foreign direct investment (FDI), in addition to interna-
tional trade, was considered as a critical channel for knowledge diffusion long before the
introduction of R&D-driven growth models around 1990. For instance, Romer (1990) under-
lines the role of FDI on filling the technology gap between developed and developing coun-
tries. He asserts that a country’s growth is closely related to its utilisation of knowledge
embodied in FDI as well as the formation of physical and human capital. In general, multina-
tional corporations (MNCs) are believed to have a strong dedication to employee training. In
other words, MNCs may provide a direct and positive impact on boosting local economic
growth through human resource development. Nevertheless, Caves (1974) has emphasised
three potential spillover benefits as indirect gains of FDI in addition to the above direct bene-
fit. Among these potential benefits, the most important one from the standpoint of developing
countries is the diffusion of knowledge to local firms. In particular, FDI can facilitate the pro-
cess of knowledge diffusion not only directly through the training of suppliers, but also indi-
rectly through labour mobility and imitation.
©2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
984 W.-H. LIU

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT