Insurgency and Ivory: The Territorial Origins of Illicit Resource Extraction in Civil Conflicts

AuthorFelix Haass
Published date01 July 2021
Date01 July 2021
DOI10.1177/0010414020957682
Subject MatterArticles
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414020957682
Comparative Political Studies
2021, Vol. 54(8) 1327 –1361
© The Author(s) 2020
Article reuse guidelines:
sagepub.com/journals-permissions
DOI: 10.1177/0010414020957682
journals.sagepub.com/home/cps
Article
Insurgency and Ivory:
The Territorial Origins
of Illicit Resource
Extraction in Civil
Conflicts
Felix Haass1,2
Abstract
The presence of natural resources makes civil conflicts more likely to erupt,
last longer, and more difficult to end. Yet rebels do not always exploit
resources wherever they are present. Why? I argue that rebels extract more
resources when they compete with governments over territorial authority.
Territorial competition facilitates black market access, generates financial
pressure, and produces governance incentives for rebels to extract natural
resources. I test this proposition in a two-tiered research design. First, I show
globally that moderate territorial control predicts more resource extraction
by rebels. Subsequently, I focus on the example of ivory poaching which
offers a rare glimpse into the usually hidden resource extraction process.
I match spatially disaggregated conflict event data to subnational poaching
data in conflict-affected African countries. Results show that rebels seeking
territorial control substantially increase poaching rates. These findings
highlight the strategic conditions under which territorial competition shapes
rebel criminal behavior.
Keywords
natural resources, civil war, rebel governance, ivory poaching
1German Institute of Global and Area Studies (GIGA), Hamburg, Germany
2University of Osnabrueck, Hamburg, Germany
Corresponding Author:
Felix Haass, German Institute of Global and Area Studies (GIGA), Neuer Jungfernstieg 21,
20354 Hamburg, Germany.
Email: felix.haass@uni-osnabrueck.de
957682CPSXXX10.1177/0010414020957682Comparative Political StudiesHaass
research-article2020
1328 Comparative Political Studies 54(8)
Introduction
When do rebel groups extract natural resources during civil conflicts? An
extensive literature links rebels’ exploitation of lootable natural resources to
armed conflict. When insurgents can mine and sell diamonds, profit from
cocaine processed from coca plants, or harvest and smuggle timber, conflicts
are more likely to erupt, last longer, and are much more difficult to end.1
Although precise estimates are difficult to obtain, the protracted conflicts
these resources help finance kill thousands of civilians and combatants alike
(Gates et al., 2012). Moreover, resource extraction incurs enormous ecologi-
cal costs, such as toxic contaminants from mining chemicals, large-scale
deforestation from illegal logging, or population-threatening hunting of high-
value wildlife (Daskin & Pringle, 2018; Gaynor et al., 2016).
Existing research, however, often assumes that when resources are present,
rebels will exploit these resources when they have an opportunity to do so.2
Yet rebels do not automatically loot resources over the course of a conflict:
almost 20% of all rebel groups between 1990 and 2012 initiated or ended at
least one type of resource extraction over the course of a conflict.3 Why?
I argue that insurgents extract resources as a consequence of their armed
struggle against a government over territorial authority. When rebels lack ter-
ritorial control, they also lack the necessary market access to start extracting
resources. Alternatively, without income or civilian support structures gener-
ated at least partially through resource extraction it is difficult for rebels to
firmly establish territorial control. Instead, it is when rebels actively compete
with a government to establish political authority over territory that they
intensify resource extraction.
I identify three mechanisms that drive the link between territorial competi-
tion and resource extraction. First, territorial competition erodes borders and
undermines law enforcement, enabling easier access to black markets where
rebels can sell or smuggle illicit goods. Second, rebels who compete with a
government over territory have organizational pressure to finance increas-
ingly expensive warfare. And third, insurgents seeking political authority
over territory can use illicit resource extraction as a governance strategy to
generate civilian cooperation. Together, these mechanisms imply that higher
levels of territorial competition should lead to more extensive resource
extraction by rebels.
I test this proposition in a two-tiered research design. In a macro setting, I
first test my main hypothesis by combining data on rebel groups’ level of ter-
ritorial control with information on rebel funding from natural resources,
using a global sample of 270 rebel groups between 1989 and 2012
(Cunningham et al., 2013; Walsh et al., 2018). Second, to investigate the
Haass 1329
proposed causal mechanisms in greater detail, I turn to a micro-level analysis
of territorial competition and illegal ivory poaching in Africa.
Ivory poaching is uniquely suited for studying the mechanisms of the
competition-extraction link, since it is a rare type of resource where we have
direct evidence on the extraction process itself. Resource extraction by rebels
is usually hidden from outside observers. This makes it extremely difficult to
empirically test theories that link conflict and resource extraction. To over-
come this challenge, I use an original data source that allows me to capture
poaching rates directly: the Monitoring of Illegally Killed Elephants (MIKE)
program under the Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species
of Wild Fauna and Flora (CITES) that collects annual poaching rates across
the African continent (CITES, 1999).
I match the spatial extent of MIKE monitoring sites to data on the geo-
graphic location of conflict events from the Armed Conflict Location and
Event Dataset (ACLED) (Raleigh et al., 2010). To distinguish territorial com-
petition from regular battlefield violence, I consider a subset of ACLED
events, such as territory acquisition or headquarter establishment. I control
for a wide range of conflict variables as well as site fixed effects to disen-
tangle the competition-extraction relationship from alternative explanations,
such as battlefield violence and state failure.
Results from both the macro- and micro analysis are consistent with my
expectation that territorial competition increases rebels’ level of resource
extraction. I show in the macro-level analysis that rebels across the globe
engage in more illegal resource exploitation when they hold moderate levels
of territory. In the micro-level setting, I document evidence that rebels who
compete with a government over the strategic control of territory increase
poaching rates by 9% to 36%. Crucially the effect of territorial competition
events on poaching rates is much stronger than the effect of all conflict events,
suggesting that the effect is driven by territorial competition instead of general
instability due to conflict. I also report conditional effects in support of the
market access, financial, and governance mechanisms specified above.
This paper helps to fill a blind spot of research on civil conflict and lootable
natural resources. Previous research largely assumes resource endowments are
exogenously given and proceeds to study the consequences of natural resources
on civil conflict onset, duration, or termination.4 I relax this assumption by
endogenizing rebels’ choice to illegally exploit resources. This allows me to
unpack the causal pathway between resource presence and exploitation. Future
research on the resources-conflict link needs to take this pathway into account
to fully understand the conditions under which resources lead to conflict.
This study also contributes to the growing body of research on rebel gov-
ernance in conflict zones (Arjona et al., 2015; Stewart, 2018). My theory, in

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT