Insurance Fraud in a Rothschild–Stiglitz World

AuthorM. Martin Boyer,Richard Peter
Date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12264
Published date01 March 2020
©2018 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol.XX, No. XX, 1–26 (2018).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12264
Insurance Fraud in a Rothschild–Stiglitz World
M. Martin Boyer
Richard Peter
Abstract
In this article, we model a competitive insurance market where policyhold-
ers privately have information about their probability of accident ex ante and
know the state of the world ex post. Wecombine costly state verification with-
out commitment and arguments from insurance contracting under adverse
selection to characterize the resulting allocations. Insurance fraud convexi-
fies the insurer’s zero expected profit condition, which can lead to complete
unraveling with low risks dropping out of the market. The standard case,
however, involves rationing of low risks, which raises their probability of
fraud and their success rate when committing it. As a result, adverse selec-
tion increases fraud in the economy. We also show that cross-subsidization
from low risks to high risks mitigates the fraud externality.Our results high-
light that adverse selection and insurance fraud interact in nontrivial ways
and have the potential to aggravate each other.
Introduction
Insurance fraud is an ongoing problem in the insurance industry. In the United States,
the Federal Bureau of Investigation estimates the annual cost of insurance fraud at
$40 billion, whereas the Coalition Against Insurance Fraud estimates that “at least $80
billion in fraudulent claims are made annually in the U.S. . .. (in) all lines of insurance.
It’s also a conservative figure because much insurance fraud goes undetected and un-
reported.”1Typesof fraud include build-up (exaggerating the loss amount), planned
M. Martin Boyer holds the Power Corporation of Canada Chair in the Department of Fi-
nance, HEC Montr´
eal (Universit´
e de Montr´
eal). Boyer can be contacted via e-mail: mar-
tin.boyer@hec.ca. Richard Peter is at the Department of Finance, University of Iowa. Peter
can be contacted via e-mail: richard-peter@uiowa.edu. Wethank Wanda Mimra, Pierre Picard,
J¨
org Schiller, and Faith Neale for their comments on a previous iteration of this article, as well
as the journal’s referees. Boyer would also like to thank Andreas Richter, Johannes Jaspersen,
and the entire team of researchersat the Munich Risk and Insurance Center for their hospitality.
This research benefited from the financial support of the Social Sciences and Humanities Re-
search Council of Canada (Grant #435-2016-1109), and of the Retirement and Savings Institute
(ire.hec.ca) at HEC Montr´
eal. The continuing support of CIRANO is also acknowledged.
1See https://www.fbi.gov/stats-services/publications/insurance-fraudfor the FBI figure and
http://www.insurancefraud.org/the-impact-of-insurance-fraud.htmfor that of the Coalition
Against Insurance Fraud.
1
117
117
Vol. 87, No. 1, 117–142 (2020).
2The Journal of Risk and Insurance
fraud (reporting a loss when none happened), lying on the policy application, and
lying on the amount invested in mitigation. Dionne et al. (1993) report that fraudulent
claims amount to at least 13 percent of all claims, and the Insurance Fraud Council es-
timates that between $5.6 and $7.7 billion were paid in excess in 2012 because of fraud-
ulent or build-up claims, representing between 13 and 17 percent of all claims paid.2
In this article, we extend the economic analysis of insurance fraud by considering
that policyholders have private information about their probability of accident ex ante
and the state of the world ex post, thereby providing the first joint analysis of adverse
selection and insurance fraud. We combine costly state verification without commit-
ment and arguments from insurance contracting under asymmetric information to
gain new insights into the effects of both types of frictions on insurance market out-
comes. Ex post moral hazard convexifies the insurer’s zero expected profit constraint,
which makes more than full coverage optimal when risk types are known. This can
help explain the existence of replacement-cost endorsements (see Dionne and Gagn´
e,
2001) and a preference for low deductibles (see Sydnor, 2010). Indifference curves
in premium/indemnity space are increasing, concave, and satisfy single crossing so
that the possibility of fraud does not alter the qualitative properties of insurance mar-
ket outcomes under adverse selection. The Rothschild–Stiglitz allocation entails no
distortion of the high-risk contract whereas low risks are shut out of the market or ra-
tioned, depending on the severity of the high-risk incentive compatibility constraint.
If they are rationed, the total amount of fraud rises in the economy. We also con-
sider cross-subsidized contracts to address those cases where the Rothschild–Stiglitz
contracts fail to be an equilibrium or are inefficient, and find that cross-subsidization
reduces the total amount of fraud in the economy. A numerical example illustrates
that adverse selection and insurance fraud interact nontrivially and can aggravate or
alleviate each other in terms of social welfare.
Existing research on insurance fraud assumes that accident probabilities are common
knowledge. It is natural to apply Townsend’s(1979) costly state verification approach
to insurance fraud. The optimal insurance contract stipulates a no-auditing region
where a fixed payment is made to the insured, and an auditing region where all
claims are audited and coverage is provided as full insurance less a deductible (see
also the standard debt contract of Gale and Hellwig, 1985). Mookherjee and Png (1989)
and Bond and Crocker (1997) show that truth telling can be achieved using stochastic
audits, which is Pareto superior to Townsend’sapproach for being more cost effective.3
Tennyson (2002) and Miyazaki (2009) explain the presence of insurance fraud by the
fact that some policyholders feel justified to pad claims (see also Dean, 2004). Tennyson
(1997) finds that the build-up of insurance claims is related to the social acceptability
of exaggerating claims, one’s personal attitude toward dishonesty (see Boyer, 2007,
for a model), and the perception of the inherent integrity of insurance institutions.
The traditional mechanism design literature has concentrated on problems where it
is optimal for all players to tell the truth, which requires the principal to commit
2See http://www.insurancefraud.org/downloads/InsuranceResearchCouncil02-15.pdf.
3Tennyson and Salsas-Forn (2002) find evidence that insurers audit rationally and that audits
are effective in deterring and detecting fraud.
2The Journal of Risk and Insurance
118

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT