Insurance Covenants in Corporate Credit Agreements

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jori.12263
Date01 March 2020
Published date01 March 2020
AuthorGreg Nini
INSURANCE COVENANTS IN CORPORATE CREDIT
AGREEMENTS
Greg Nini
ABSTRACT
In a large sample of private credit agreements of publicly traded firms,
nearly all agreements contain at least a boilerplate provision requiring the
borrower to purchase insurance. In about 80 percent of the agreements,
the insurance covenant is more explicit. Four additional features of the
insurance covenant are quite common: requirements of coverage for
specific risks, naming the lender as a loss payee, mandating that any
insurance proceeds be used to repay the loan, and explicit permission for
the borrower to self-insure. Credit agreements contain more stringent
insurance requirements for borrowers that pose higher credit risk. The
insurance requirements are strongly positively correlated with the loan
being secured by collateral, which suggests that insurance creates value by
protecting lenders from unexpected changes in seniority that might
happen following the destruction of collateral. Insurance covenants are an
important ingredient of credit agreements designed to create a very safe
claim for senior, secured lenders.
INTRODUCTION
Corporate credit agreements frequently require the borrower to purchase
insurance, providing one answer to the long-debated question why publicly
traded corporations would demand insurance. Since the seminal work of Mayers
and Smith (1982) first highlighted that the corporate form provides maximal
diversification opportunities, researchers have looked for alternatives to risk
aversion to explain the corporate demand for insurance. Mayers and Smith (1987)
and others have pointed to covenants in lending agreements as one source of
corporate demand and have offered theories to identify the value that insurance
covenants can create.
The goal of this article is to provide large-sample evidence on the use and nature of
insurance covenants in credit agreements for publicly traded companies. I provide
Greg Nini is at LeBow College of Business, Drexel University. Nini can be contacted via e-mail:
gpn26@drexel.edu.
©2018 The Journal of Risk and Insurance. Vol. 9999, No. 9999, 1–21 (2018).
DOI: 10.1111/jori.12263
1
95
95
Vol. 87, No. 1, 95–115 (2020).
evidence that loan contracts nearly always require that borrowers have some form of
insurance and in many cases tailor the requirements to the borrowers’ specific
situation. In addition to requirements to have insurance, credit agreements also
frequently include four additional provisions: (1) requirements that borrowers
purchase specific types of coverage, such as liability or property insurance; (2)
requirements that lenders be named as additional loss payees; (3) requirements that
the proceeds from any insurance payments be used to pay down outstanding loan
balances; and (4) explicit permission that borrowers may self-insure. Given that over
three-quarters of public firms use private credit agreements (Sufi, 2007), insurance
covenants are indeed an important source to explain the depth and variety of
corporate insurance seen in practice.
I establish these facts using a set of more than 4,000 credit agreements entered into by
publicly traded firms in the United States during the years 1996 through 2010. In each
of the agreements, I read the section related to insurance and code the presence or
absence of each of the four provisions.
Using these data, I show empirically that the provisions are related to a number of
borrower-specific characteristics. Consistent with prevailing theory, I find that the
credit quality of the borrowers is significantly related to the use of various insurance
provisions. Firms posing higher credit risk are significantly more likely to be required
to buy insurance for specific risks, more likely to name their lender as a loss payee,
and more likely to be required to use any insurance proceeds to pay down loan
balances. The estimated effects are quite large; compared to firms with an A credit
rating, B-rated firms are about twice as likely to have insurance covenants that require
specific coverage.
This result is consistent with existing theories that explain insurance covenants
as a means to avoid underinvestment problems created by risky debt. Myers
(1977) shows that management of levered firms may limit investment if some of
the returns to a project accrue to creditors in the form of reduced credit risk.
Since the underinvestment problem worsens as firms become more levered,
insurance can create value by reducing the probability of insolvency, as shown
in Garven and McMinn (1993). For firms with higher credit risk, the benefit of
insurance is larger, since it takes a smaller loss to move such firms closer to
insolvency.
I also find that stricter insurance covenants are considerably more common for
loans that are secured with collateral. Secured loans are much more likely to
require specific coverage, often insuring the assets serving as collateral, much
more likely to name the lender as an additional loss payee, and more likely to
require prepayment from insurance proceeds. I conjecture that the insurance
requirement creates value by limiting the possibility that secured lenders face an
unexpected change in priority following an insurable loss. For example, in the
event that a fire destroys a firm’s inventory that is pledged as collateral to a
secured lender, the secured lender loses its priority relative to the firm’s other
creditors. The risk of such an event weakens the value of providing collateral,
which recent empirical work (e.g., Rauh and Sufi, 2010) has shown is used
strategically by borrowers. If, however, the borrower were required to purchase
2THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
2The Journal of Risk and Insurance
96

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT