Insurance, Consumer Search, and Equilibrium Price Distributions

AuthorŞ. Nuray Akın,Brennan C. Platt
Published date01 June 2014
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1539-6975.2013.01515.x
Date01 June 2014
©
DOI: 10.1111/j.1539-6975.2013.01515.x
397
INSURANCE,CONSUMER SEARCH,AND EQUILIBRIUM
PRICE DISTRIBUTIONS
S¸. NurayAkın
Brennan C. Platt
ABSTRACT
We examine a service market with two frictions: search is required to ob-
tain price quotes, and insurance coverage for the service reduces household
search effort. While fewer draws from a price distribution will directly raise
a household’s average price, the indirect effect of reduced search on price
competition has a much greater impact, accounting for at least 89 percent
of increased average expenditures. In this environment, a monopolist in-
surer will exacerbate the moral hazard by offering full insurance. A compet-
itive insurance market typically results in partial insurance and significant
price dispersion, yet a second-best contract would offer even less insurance
coverage.
INTRODUCTION
In most markets where insurance plays a prominent role (such as medical services
or auto repairs), the price of a particular service varies significantly from one firm
to another.1In a typical market, consumers respond to price dispersion by obtaining
price quotes from a number of firms and selecting the lowest price. However, when
an insurance company ultimately pays for most of the service, the consumer’s incen-
tive to search is dramatically reduced. This article studies insurance contracts in an
environment with moral hazard due to search.
An insurance contract (or policy) consists of the premium charged to households
as well as a coinsurance rate, defined as the percentage of an insurance claim that
the household pays out-of-pocket. In offering a particular policy, an insurer must
consider the incentives it creates for both households and service providers. We depict
S. Nuray Akın works in the Department of Economics, University of Miami. Brennan C.
Platt works in the Department of Economics, Brigham Young University. We are grate-
ful to Marco Bassetto, Hulya Eraslan, Boyan Jovanovic, David Kelly, Manuel Santos, Alan
Sorensen, and Val Lambson for their valuable comments. All remaining errors are our
own.
1Sorensen (2000) provides an empirical investigation of price dispersion in the prescrip-
tion drug market (pricing the same drug across retailers). He documents that, on aver-
age, the highest posted price is over 50 percent above the lowest available price; fur-
thermore, differences in pharmacy characteristics can account for at most one-third of the
dispersion.
S¸.
The Journal of Risk and Insurance, 2013, Vol. 81, No. 2, 397–429
398 THE JOURNAL OF RISK AND INSURANCE
this in a general equilibrium model in which the interactions between these agents
endogenously determine the insurance policy, the distribution of service prices, and
the search intensity of households.
Moral hazard can be measured as the increase in the expected total cost of the event
due to the presence of a particular insurance contract. Wedecompose two effects that
contribute to this rise in expected cost. First, a direct effect occurs when consumers
request fewer quotes from the same distribution. This was studied in Dionne (1984),
which we extend by identifying a second indirect effect, which happens in equilibrium
because requesting fewer quotes results in less price competition among the service
providers, shifting the distribution toward higher prices. Indeed, we find that regard-
less of parameter values, the latter effect is at least 8.6 times bigger than the former,
or in other words, is responsible for at least 89 percent of the cost increase caused by
moral hazard.2Thus, the general equilibrium feedback is a much larger concern in
the incentive problem.
Wealso characterize the second-best insurance policy, which selects a coinsurance rate
that balances consumption smoothing against incentives to search. This is compared
with the insurance policy from two different insurance market structures: monopoly
and perfect competition.
Surprisingly, even though a monopolist insurerhas the most ability to promote com-
petition among service firms, it has no incentive to do so. Instead, it offers full in-
surance, resulting in no search and a high service price. While this leads to high
expected payouts on insurance, these are passed on to households in their insurance
premium. In addition, households are willing to pay a larger risk premium on top
of it precisely because they face greater variance in wealth should they remain unin-
sured. To the best of our knowledge, we are the first to provide this result in the
literature.
On the other hand, a perfectly competitive (PC) policy includes some coinsurance
but still less than the second-best policy, due to search externalities. The insurer only
optimizes with respect to the policy’s direct effect on its clients, neglecting the indirect
benefits of extra search effort.
In our model, there is a continuum of ex ante identical households and service firms,
and an insurance firm. Households face a random event (such as an auto accident or
health problem)3with some fixed probability. If the event occurs, the household must
2A similar flavor arises in Fershtman and Fishman (1994) and Armstrong, Vickers, and Zhou
(2009). Both articles consider the effect of an exogenous price cap in a market with search
frictions (but no insurance contracts). While the cap necessarily reduces the high end of the
price distribution, it has the unintended consequence of reducing the benefits of search. As
fewer consumers seek additional quotes, retailers compete less vigorously and the low end
of the price distribution will rise; indeed, consumers can be left worse off after the imposition
of the price cap.
3This is purely a monetary loss, and thus assumes away any irreparable damage. Ma and
McGuire (1997) model health shocks as a monetary loss that can be partially recovered de-
pending on the quantity and quality of health care purchased.
INSURANCE, CONSUMER SEARCH, AND EQUILIBRIUM PRICE DISTRIBUTIONS 399
hire a service firm to fully repair4the damage. This service is homogenous across
the service firms, but each firm may charge a different price. Households know the
distribution of offered prices, but can only learn the price charged by a particular firm
through costly search effort.
Households can insure against this event by purchasing a policy offered by the insur-
ance firm. If the event occurs, the policy reimburses a stipulated fraction of the actual
price paid. All service firms are within the insurer’s approved network, meaning they
have agreed not to charge more than a maximum price.
Search is simultaneous, as in Burdett and Judd (1983); that is, a household receives all
quotes at the same time. A simultaneous search environmentcan generate equilibrium
price dispersion even though firms and households are homogeneous.5Our model
extends Burdett and Judd (1983) in threenoteworthy ways: households are risk averse,
insurance contracts are incorporated, and quotes are obtained with a probability that
depends on search effort. The last feature greatly improves tractability and reduces
the number of equilibria.
Our work contributes to a broad literature on moral hazard problems, which occur
whenever the presence of insurance distorts incentives for the insured, causing an
increase in expected payout.6Two other forms of moral hazard are well known.
First, the insured person may exercise less precaution (such as defensive driving),
increasing the probability of loss. Second, the insured person may increase his con-
sumption of the covered service (such as medical appointments), increasing the
size of loss. These have been extensively studied, beginning with the work of Ar-
row (1963), Pauly (1968), Smith (1968), Zeuckhauser (1970), and Ehrlich and Becker
(1972).
However, moral hazard in search has received much less attention, with the only
formal analyses in Dionne (1981, 1984).7In a model where the coinsurance rate is
taken as exogenous and the distribution of prices is fixed regardless of the number
of quotes requested by households, Dionne identifies the negative incentive effect of
insurance on search behavior and hence on expected service prices. However, this
omits a crucial (and, as we show, larger) component of the story: the endogenous
response of firms to household search.
4This indivisibility of repairs eliminates an intensive margin that the household might adjust
(or insurer might limit) in response to the price. This seems reasonable for many urgent
health expenditures (such as unexpected surgery or filling a vital prescription) or major auto
reconstruction, in which the choice is essentially discrete (to do it or not), and search is limited
by the need to choose a provider rather quickly.
5Baye, Morgan, and Scholten (2006) provide a comprehensive and insightful review of models
of search that can produce equilibrium price dispersion. Sequential search can produce price
dispersion with homogeneous buyers if search is nonstationary due to deadlines; see Akin
and Platt (Forthcoming).
6Rowell and Connelly (2012) provides an extensive history on the usage of the term moral
hazard.
7Arrow (1963) mentions the potential problem: “Insurance removes the incentive on the part
of individuals, patients, and physicians to shop around for better prices for hospitalization
and surgical care.”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT