INSTITUTIONAL OWNERSHIP AND EARNING MANAGEMENT BY BANK HOLDING COMPANIES

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jfir.12120
AuthorElyas Elyasiani,Yuan Wen,Rongrong Zhang
Published date01 June 2017
Date01 June 2017
INSTITUTIONAL OWNERSHIP AND EARNING MANAGEMENT BY
BANK HOLDING COMPANIES
Elyas Elyasiani
Temple University
Yuan Wen
SUNY New Paltz
Rongrong Zhang
Georgia Southern University
Abstract
We explore the role of institutio nal investors as a source of market di scipline in
mitigating earning managem ent (EMGT) by bank holding com panies (BHCs). We
propose that ownership by monitoring institutions ( institutional investor s with large
and long-term stakes and ind ependence from managers) is associated w ith less EMGT
because they have greater incenti ves/skills for monitoring their i nvestees than other
shareholders. We nd that EMG T by BHCs is negatively associat ed with ownership
by monitoring institution s for larger and riskier banks and for th e post-SunTrust
decision period. Nonmonitor ing institutional ownership is un associated or in some
cases weakly or even positively assoc iated with EMGT. Our ndings suggest th at
regulators should facilit ate ownership by monitorin g institutions as a complemen t to
regulation.
JEL Classification: G21, G23, G38
I. Introduction
We explore the role of institutional investors in mitigating earnings management
(EMGT) in publicly traded U.S. bank holding companies (BHCs). EMGT by banks is of
interest to academic researchers and regulators because it deepens the information
asymmetry between corporate insiders and outside stakeholders (creditors, shareholders,
and regulators) and thereby potentially elevates social costs. Institutional owners, in
particular, those with large equity stakes and longer term investment horizons, have
strong incentives to serve as monitors to limit managerial opportunism and risky
accounting practices, especially when these practices are clearly detrimental to the
interest of the rm. This is because these owners benet from monitoring to a larger
extent, compared to other shareholders, and have the voting power and skills to achieve
the desired results.
Extant studies nd that corporate managers manipulate nancial reporting for
various reasons, for example, to meet or beat analyst forecasts (Habib and Hossain 2008)
or to increase the value of their equity holdings (Cheng and Wareld 2005; Bergstresser
The Journal of Financial Research Vol. XL, No. 2 Pages 147178 Summer 2017
147
© 2017 The Southern Finance Association and the Southwestern Finance Association
RAWLS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS, TEXAS TECH UNIVERSITY
PUBLISHED FOR THE SOUTHERN AND SOUTHWESTERN
FINANCE ASSOCIATIONS BY WILEY-BLACKWELL PUBLISHING
and Philippon 2006). In regulated industries such as banking, managers may also engage
in EMGT to: avoid lawsuits based on prudent-man laws,
1
escape disciplinary actions
from bank examiners, pass regulatory tests for capital adequacy, reduce the chances of
their applications for mergers and acquisitions being denied, and boost their
performance-based compensations. Moreover, banks may practice EMGT to avoid
the loss of major clients for guarantee services (standby letters of credit and loan
commitments) and counterparty positions in derivatives, and to eschew negative
announcements to the market. In these cases, EMGT takes the form of increasing the
earnings. In some other cases, however, EMGT could decrease earnings, for example, to
raise cookie jar reserves or to reduce the stock price before insidersshare purchases
(Badertscher et al. 2009).
EMGT patterns of banks may be dissimilar from those of nonbank rms because
they are substantially more leveraged, more heavily regulated, and more opaque
(Diamond 1984; Morgan 2002; Flannery, Kwan, and Nimalendran 2004). Moreover,
assets and liabilities of banks (loans and deposits) are unique and dissimilar from those of
nonbank rms. The effect of regulation on bank EMGT is not clear-cut. On the one hand,
regulatory oversight, fear of prosecution, and concerns about possible loss of business
due to regulatory violation deter banks from engaging in EMGT. On the other hand, bank
managers could be motivated to engage in EMGT to avoid regulatory intervention and
disciplinary action, as well as attract demand for their guarantee products. For example,
regulatory capital requirement may encourage banks to understate their loan loss
provisions as a percentage of total loans (LLP) or to manage their realized securities
gains/losses as a ratio of total assets (RSG) in order to articially improve their capital
ratios (Moyer 1990; Beatty, Chamberlain, and Magliolo 1995). Cheng, Wareld, and Ye
(2011) show that the motivation for EMGT by banks depends on the likelihood of
regulatory intervention; banks with low capital (likely to be subject to regulatory
intervention) show strong incentives for EMGT whereas those with adequate capital do
not. Regulatory intervention in response to EMGT by banks could take the form of
downgrading the CAMELS rating of the bank and/or regulatory actions by the U.S.
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC).
2
The tools employed by banks for EMGT are also dissimilar from those used by
nonbank rms because bank assets and liabilities (loans and deposits) are unique in
nature. Bank managers can articially inate earnings by understating loan loss
provisions and/or manipulating realized securities gains/losses (Beatty, Chamberlain,
and Magliolo 2002). We use the absolute value of the discretionary component of loan
loss provisions as a ratio of total loans (ABS_DLLP) and the absolute value of the
discretionary component of realized securities gains/losses as a ratio of total assets
1
Prudent-man laws are designed to protect small investors. They allow investors to seek damages from
duciaries that do not invest in their best interests. These laws incentivize the duciaries to invest in safer assets
(because these assets can be easily defended in court) and encourage them to engage in EMGT to produce a rosier
picture.
2
See the next section and footnotes 5 and 6 for an example and more details on regulatory action. We thank an
anonymous referee for raising this point, and Julapa Jagtiani of the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia for
discussion.
148 The Journal of Financial Research
(ABS_DRSG) as our measures of EMGT. These components qualify as measures of
EMGT because they are determined not by innate factors but rather by the discretion of
the managers.
The existing literature documents that institutional investors play a positive
role in corporate governance via inuencing CEO compensation schemes (Khan,
Dharwadkar, and Brandes 2005), demanding conservative accounting practices
(Ramalingegowda and Yu, 2011), and/or affecting other governance-related issues
such as board independence and removal of poison pills (Gillan and Starks 2000).
Institutional owners of nancial rms are also known to curtail rm risk, advance
rm performance, and reduce their cost of debt (Cheng, Elyasiani, and Jia 2011;
Elyasiani, Jia, and Mao 2010; Elyasiani and Jia 2008).
3
However, no study has
addressed the effect of institutional ownersmonitoring on EMGT by BHCs. We
seek to ll this void.
We focus on the monitoring institutions”—institutional investors with
strong incentives, skills, and voting power to monitor. This group is dened as
including investors that are (1) dedicatedas classied by Bushee (1998, 2001) and
(2) independentfrom the management as classied by Brickley, Lease, and Smith
(1988). Because of differences in the client base, liquidity needs, and demographics,
institutional investors differ in their ownership concentration and investment
horizons (Gasper, Massa, and Matos 2005). In particular, dedicated institutions tend
to have large and long-term holdings in only a few rms. These features give rise to
relationship investing,rendering short-term trading increasingly unattractive and
monitoring increasingly desirable (Hirschman 1970). Independent institutional
investors are those that are less likely to have business connections with their
investee rms and therefore do not have concerns about losing business with the
latter.
We propose that monitoring institutions are associated with less EMGT for
three reasons. First, institutional investors with long investment horizons do not focus
on short-term performance , and hence, managers of the ir investee rms have less
incentive to engage in EMGT to sho w better performance (Bushee 20 01; Koh 2007).
Attig et al. (2013) nd that the cost of equity is lower in the presence of institutional
investors with long invest ment horizons because of impr oved monitoring and
information quality. Along the same lines, Elyasiani, Jia, and Mao (2010) nd a
negative relation between the cost of debt and institutional ownership stability.
Similarly, Stein (1988, 1989) suggests that the presence of shareholders with relatively
long investment horizons can mitigate managersincentives for myopic investment
decisions. In the same contex t, Burns, Kedia, and Lipson (20 10) nd that ownership
by short-horizon institutional investors is associated with higher discretionary
accruals, suggesting that the presence of these investors inc reases EMGT. It can
therefore be expected that improv ed monitoring and enhanced inform ation quality due
to longer horizon institut ional ownership also limit EM GT by BHCs. Second, the large
3
Institutional investors include investment companies, independent investment advisors, public pension
funds, bank trusts, insurers, and so on.
Institutional Ownership and Earning Management 149

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT