Institutional Monitoring: Evidence from the F‐Score

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/jbfa.12123
Published date01 September 2015
AuthorKainan Wang,Blerina Bela Zykaj,Chune Young Chung,Chang Liu
Date01 September 2015
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 42(7) & (8), 885–914, September/October 2015, 0306-686X
doi: 10.1111/jbfa.12123
Institutional Monitoring: Evidence from
the F-Score
CHUNE YOUNG CHUNG,CHANG LIU,KAINAN WANG AND BLERINA BELA ZYKAJ
Abstract: The extant literature shows that institutional investors engage in corporate gover-
nance to enhance a firm’s long-term value. Measuring firm performance using the F-Score,
we examine the persistent monitoring role of institutional investors and identify the financial
aspects of a firm that institutional monitoring improves. We find strong evidence that long-
term institutions with large shareholdings consistently improve a firm’s F-Score and that
such activity occurs primarily through the enhancement of the firm’s operating efficiency.
Other institutions reduce a firm’s F-Score. Moreover, we find evidence that, while monitoring
institutions improve a firm’s financial health, transient (followed by non-transient) institutions
trade on this information.
Keywords: institutional investor, F-Score, monitoring, financial strength
1. INTRODUCTION
Institutional investors’ stake in the equity market has significantly increased in the last
few decades, leading to many studies on the role of institutional investors in corporate
governance. This issue became even more important leading up to and during the
recent financial crisis, when institutional investors exerted an allegedly negative impact
on the market by pressuring management to increase risk-taking behavior for more
short-term profits (e.g., Della Croce et al., 2011; and Erkens et al., 2012).
The literature offers two opposing views on this subject: an institution could take
either a passive role (i.e., with a short-term focus and little incentive to influence firm
management) or an active monitoring role (i.e., with strong incentives to improve
firm management through monitoring). Bushee (1998, 2001) classifies institutional
investors based on their implied incentives and shows that transient institutional
owners (i.e., institutions with high portfolio turnovers and a reliance on momentum
trading) encourage myopic activities and, if present in large numbers, may cause
managers to focus on short-term investments. By contrast, non-transient institutional
The first author is from the School of Business Administration, College of Business and Economics, Chung-
Ang University, Seoul, Korea. The second author is from the Department of Financial Economics and
Information Systems, College of Business, Hawai’i Pacific University, Honolulu, HI. The third and fourth
authors are from the Department of Finance, College of Business and Innovation, University of Toledo,
OH. The authors gratefully acknowledge the helpful comments of Editor Peter F.Pope and one anonymous
referee that greatly improved the paper.
Address for correspondence: Kainan Wang, Department of Finance, College of Business and Innovation,
University of Toledo, OH 43606, USA.
e-mail: kainan.wang@utoledo.edu
C
2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 885
886 CHUNG, LIU, WANG AND ZYKAJ
owners play a monitoring role in the firm by restraining managers’ myopic behaviors.
In the same spirit, Chen et al. (2007) use a cost–benefit framework to study the
attributes of institutions that are likely to be firm monitors, showing that not all
institutions have the incentives and means to monitor firm management. Rather,
independent and long-term institutions with large shareholdings are more likely to
engage in monitoring behaviors.1Yan and Zhang (2005) also argue that institutional
investors have different investment horizons due to differences in investment ob-
jectives, restrictions, and styles. They show that short-term institutions – institutions
with high portfolio turnovers and a short-term investment strategy (i.e., transient
institutions) – are more informed than other institutions and are thus more likely to
trade on information about firm value rather than monitor firm management because
the monitoring benefits would realize only in the long term, conflicting with their
short-term-focused investment strategy.
The ultimate goal of institutional monitoring is to improve a firm’s financial
strength, which in turn increases future stock returns.2Studies have captured the
monitoring effect of institutions by focusing on specific corporate events. For example,
research has examined institutional investors’ influence on executive compensation,
R&D investments, seasoned equity offerings, mergers and acquisitions, earnings
management, payout policy, and CEO turnover. Specifically, these studies gauge the
effectiveness of institutional monitoring by examining stock returns around a major
firm event.
These studies produce mixed evidence about whether institutional investors ef-
fectively monitor management and/or whether their governance actions increase
firm value. Some papers focus on ‘institutional activism’ and argue that institutional
investors actively monitor the firm and that such monitoring is effective. For example,
O’Barr and Conley (1992) find that institutional investors utilize proxy contests to
affect important firm decisions such as antitakeover amendments, R&D investments,
and CEO compensation. Karpoff (1999) and Gillan and Starks (2000) show that insti-
tutional investors actively influence corporate governance by presenting shareholder
proposals at shareholder meetings. Other more recent studies show that institutions
broadly influence managers’ value-maximizing decisions such as R&D investments
(Bushee, 1998), executive compensation (Almazan et al., 2005), privatization (Weir
et al., 2005), and capital structure (Chung and Wang, 2014). Thus, these studies find
empirical evidence that monitoring institutions (i.e., large shareholders with long-
term investment strategies) have incentives to monitor firm management and that
their monitoring is effective.
However, some papers find counter-evidence about active institutional monitoring.
For instance, Smith (1996) and Del Guercio and Hawkins (1999) show that active
institutional monitoring may not substantially influence firm performance, and Coffee
(1991) and Bhide (1994) find that the costs of active monitoring can be greater
than its benefits. Given the increased market liquidity of recent decades, it may
1 Other studies also find empirical evidence that institutions with large shareholdings reap greater benefits
than smaller investors with a short-term horizon from collecting information and improving corporate
governance, as vigorous monitoring consequently improves firm value. These investors tend to influence
firm management to ensure that they maintain the objective of maximizing the firm’s long-term value rather
than meeting short-term earnings goals (Shleifer and Vishny, 1986, 1997; Dobrzynski, 1993; Huddart, 1993;
Monks and Minow, 1995; Gillan and Starks, 2000).
2 The monitoring role of institutional investors does not contradict or substitute for their informational
advantage and may, in fact, even be enhanced by it.
C
2015 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT